The Forward-Discount Puzzle in Central and Eastern Europe.
INTRODUCTIONThe common observation that exchange rate changes deviate systematically from the forward rate so that excess returns are available from borrowing low interest rate, funding currency for an investment in higher rate units is called the forward-discount puzzle. This paper uses a two-regime model to understand more about crash risk by assessing uncovered interest parity (UIP) deviations in a range of CEE countries and by using a hidden Markov model (HMM) to divide the deviations into two categories: those where the high-yield currency appreciates against the lower interest rate unit (adding a capital gain to the funding premium) and those where the high-yield currency falls much more than would be anticipated by UIP. In the first case, the conditions are favourable for inflow of capital to the higher interest rate unit. It would be possible to make profitable carry-trades where funds are borrowed in the lower rate unit currency, transferred into the currency with the higher interest rate for the same period as the borrowing and then exchanged back and repaid at the end of the contract. These are times of relative calm in the foreign exchange market. In the second case, these carry-trades would lose money and the sharp depreciation of the high-yield currency would be associated with exchange rate crisis.
The first regime might be called the period of 'calm' and is a much more common occurrence. The second period is rare and could be called 'crisis'. A hidden Markov model uses the potential carry-trade profits to identify the most likely regime and the probability of switching from a calm regime to one of crisis for each exchange rate. The model can be extended to assess the way that these probabilities are affected by exogenous events such as international risk aversion and changes in US interest rates. These exogenous factors increase the risk of experiencing an exchange rate crisis and can be used to compare how vulnerable each country is to these type of external shocks.
This paper adds to the evidence that the forward-discount puzzle is explained as a compensation for taking crash risk, builds on the use of nonlinear methods and greatly extends and expands on the use of HMM models for understanding the forward-discount puzzle. This paper also contributes to the literature on sudden stops as the probability of a foreign exchange crisis is calculated and the way that this probability is affected by international risk factors is also presented. The rest of this paper proceeds as follows: "Literature" section discusses the forward-discount puzzle, "The hidden Markov model" section presents the hidden Markov model, "Analysis of Results" section analyses the initial results, "Exogenous Influences on Regime SwitchingProbabilities" section considers exogenous influences on the probability of switching from one regime to another, and "Conclusion" section concludes.
LITERATURE
The forward rate today is the rate that currencies can be exchanged in the future. Covered interest parity (CIP) asserts that, given the free flow of international capital and competitive markets, the difference between the spot rate and the forward rate must be equal to the interest rate differential for the two currencies for the same period.
[F.sub.t,j]/[S.sub.t] x (1 + [i.sup.*.sub.t,j]) = (1 + [i.sub.t,j]) (1)
where [F.sub.t,j] is the forward exchange rate at time t for domestic currency in terms of overseas for j periods ahead; [S.sub.t] is spot exchange rate under the same terms at time t; [i.sub.t,j] is the interest rate for the home currency in period f for j periods ahead; [i.sup.*.sub.t,j] is the interest rate for the overseas currency at time t for j periods ahead.
Therefore,
[F.sub.t,j]/[S.sub.t] = (1 + [i.sub.t,j])/(1 + [i.sup.*.sub.t,j]) (2)
Re-arranging
[F.sub.t,j]-[S.sub.t]/[S.sub.t] = ([i.sub.t,j] - [i.sup.*.sub.t,j])/ (1 + [i.sup.*.sub.t,j] (3)
Assuming rational expectations and no financial frictions, the forward rate should be the best unbiased estimate of the future spot rate and therefore, Eq. 3 becomes.
E[S.sub.t+j] - [S.sub.t]/[S.sub.t] = ([i.sub.t,j] - [i.sup.*.sub.t,j])/ (1 + [i.sup.*.sub.t,j]
if [i.sup.*] is relatively small, this can be approximated by
E[S.sub.t+j]- [S.sub.t] = [i.sub.t,j] - [i.sup.*.sub.t,j] (5)
where [S.sub.t] is the log of the exchange rate at time t, [S.sub.t+j] is the log of the exchange rate at t plus j, [i.sub.t,j] is the j-period interest rate at time t, and * [i.sub.t,j] is the foreign currency j-period interest rate at time t.
Assuming that CIP holds (1) so that the forward rate can account for the interest rate differential, a test of UIP can take the form of
[DELTA][S.sub.t+j] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1] [f.sub.t+j] + [epsilon] (6)
where [DELTA][S.sub.t+j] is the change in the log of the exchange rate between period t and j, [f.sub.t+j] is the forward-discount expressed as the difference between the logs of the spot rate and the forward rate for j periods ahead of t; [epsilon] is an error term, while [[beta].sub.0] and [[beta].sub.1] are the coefficients to be estimated. If UIP holds, [[beta].sub.0] should be equal to zero and [[beta].sub.1] should be equal to one as again the forward rate should be an unbiased estimate of the future exchange rate.
However, this standard test of UIP consistently finds that estimates of [[beta].sub.1] are less than one. A meta-study by Froot (1990) found that the 75 published estimates had an average value of -0.88 for [[beta].sub.1]. An investment that takes advantage of this deviation by borrowing the low interest rate funding currency for a deposit in the higher interest rate investment currency is called the carry-trade. The evidence that the carry-trade is profitable is consistent with the forward-discount puzzle.
As UIP is a key component of international financial theory, there has been a tremendous effort to understand this puzzle. See Froot (1990), Hodrick (1987) and Engel (1996, 2014) for a summary of the vast literature in this area. Some suggest that it is the lack of stationarity in the series that causes estimation problems. See Engel (1996) and Roll and Yan (2000) for example. Others like Bansal and Dahlquist (1999) argue that the forward-discount puzzle is really an issue for developed rather than developing nations. Chinn and Meredith (2004) make an assessment of UIP using 10-year bond yields to suggest that the puzzle applies to the short-term but not long-term rates. It may also be associated with factors like heterogeneous market agents or asymmetry of information. See Bacchetta and van Wincoop (2012) for a survey of contributions in this area. There is also a wide ranging discussion over whether, once the assumption of risk-neutrality is abandoned, the apparent breakdown is the result of failing to correctly account for this risk. This is the avenue that is explored here.
Risk premium
If investors are risk averse and form their expectations rationally, the negative estimate for [beta] could mean that investors required additional return for holding foreign currency assets and Eq. 6 can be augmented with a term that would account for this risk premium.
E[[DELTA][S.sub.t+j]] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1] [f.sub.t+j] + [[beta].sub.2][rp.sup.re.sub.t+j] + [epsilon] (7)
where [rp.sup.re.sub.t,j] is a rational expectations risk premium at time t for j periods ahead. This seemed reasonable for the original US-centric research, but it means that none US residents require a risk premium for investing at home. Canova and Marrinan (1993) find that this risk premium switches from positive to negative as relative interest rates change and that the risk premium has a large variance, serial correlation and has volatility clustering. Fama (1984) finds that the variation in the risk premium is much larger than the variation in the exchange rate or the forward rate and that there is a negative correlation between the premium and the expected spot rate. Froot (1990) discovers that short rates consistently predict excess returns even outside currency markets. For foreign exchange, stock, bond and commodity markets, a one percentage annualised increase in the short-term interest rate is associated with about a three percentage point reduction in annualised excess returns. This all seems to undermine the simple risk premium approach to the forward-discount puzzle.
Engel (1996) has identified that this risk premium only holds under rational expectations. Market expectations may differ from the information that is used to test Eq. 6. This divergence in expectations can be divided into two types: where the econometrician has more information that the agent (the agent gradually learns the model as was the case when floating exchange rates returned in 1973) or where the agent has information that the econometrician does not have (there may be peso problems where a large depreciation is anticipated that has not previously been recorded in the data). In each of these situations, we could expect the asymmetry to dissipate over time as agents learn and more data become available. This has not happened.
Another avenue of enquiry will seek support for the risk premium approach and explanation for its volatility by looking for a relationship with common risk factors. Burnside et al. (2011) assess whether carry-returns are correlated with conventional risk factors like the equity risk premium or real consumption growth and volatility indices. They find limited correlation. McCallum (1994) assumes that [rp.sup.re] is a stochastic process and asks whether there are reasonable grounds for this to be negatively correlated with E([S.sub.t+1] -[S.sub.t]) as is found empirically. He concludes that this residual represents all the other factors that are not in the model rather than a risk premium.
Engel (1996, p. 148) says that [rp.sup.re] could represent 'expected profit opportunities' As has been seen, these expected profit opportunities are large and highly variable. There are a number of studies that have assessed the skewed nature of the returns that are associated with the carry-trade. These explanations are usually grouped under the term crash risk.
Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009) show how this crash risk can be caused by the interaction of illiquidity, margin calls and the evaporation of funding for speculation. When conditions deteriorate, investors seek to exit the carry position, liquidity declines, banks become more cautious about funding speculative positions and an increase in margin requirements, together with a reduction in funding, lead to spirals of selling and exaggerated price movements.
Brunnermeier et al. (2008) develop a general model of crash risk, which is due to the sudden unwinding of the carry-trade. The crash happens when risk appetite and funding-liquidity decrease and carry positions are swiftly unwound.
A potential carry-trade is calculated
[z.sub.t+1] [equivalent to] ([i.sup.*] - i) - [DELTA][s.sub.t+1] (8)
where [z.sub.t+1] is the return in excess of the prediction of UIP as i* is the overseas three-month interest rate and i is the domestic three-month interest rate and [DELTA][s.sub.s+1] is the change in the log of the exchange rate measured as foreign currency per US dollar Brunnermeier et al. (2008, pp. 8-9). They find that carry-trades have large Sharpe ratios, negative skewness and positive excess kurtosis. This is crash risk. There are large potential losses that can cause severe financial distress.
Spronk et al. (2013) augment a traditional heterogeneous agent model with carry-traders in addition to fundamental and chartist traders. Traders adjust their strategy towards those that are most successful. The carry-trade is built while conditions are calm. The model is able to replicate the heavy tails, excess volatility and volatility clustering that is evident in foreign exchange returns.
Jurek (2014) tries to quantify the crash risk by using out-of-the-money put options to hedge the risk of a sharp depreciation of the investment currency. By comparing the performance of hedged and un-hedged positions, he finds that less than one-third of carry-trade excess returns can be explained by crash risk. Burnside et al. (2011) use a similar method and find similar results. However, the focus in each of these cases is G20 with only Australia, New Zealand, South Africa and Norway among the traditional carry-trade countries. The variability of funding and the changes in liquidity are likely to be much greater in emerging economies. Hayward and Holscher (2014) investigated Central and Eastern European exchange rates and find that during periods of high international risk aversion the carry-trade experiences much lower returns and returns that are characterised by large-skew and kurtosis. It appears that the returns that are available under normal or calm conditions are a compensation for taking the risk of large losses when risk aversion rises and liquidity disappears. Carry-trade profits and the break down in UIP only seem to happen during the calm period.
THE HIDDEN MARKOV MODEL
A Markov process depends only on the previous state. A Markov model describes the probability of moving from one set of states to another. Markov models have been used to understand a wide range of phenomena from weather forecasting, speech recognition and internet search. If the states that are to be explained can be observed, the probability of being in a particular state and the probability that there is a switch from one state to another can be estimated from a sample. However, in many cases the states cannot be observed and then the states as well as the transition probabilities must be estimated from the data with a hidden Markov model (HMM).
Hamilton (1988) used a HMM to incorporate discrete changes in expectations about Fed policy to improve the match between the expectations theory and the term structure of interest rates. This technique assumes that there are unobserved market-expectation regimes and that the adjustment from one state to another is governed by a set of probabilities. Hamilton (1989) also analysed the performance of postwar US GNP with adjustments from periods that are termed recessions to those that are called expansions. The parameters of an ARIMA representation of US GNP shift between the two regimes so that in periods of recession the underlying growth rate is three percentage points lower than it is during the expansionary period.
Schaller and Norden (1997) used the same method to assess stock returns in two regimes, uncovering strong evidence of regime switching between bull and bear markets in the mean and variance of US stock returns. They also find that that the response of stock returns to the price-dividend ratio is asymmetric as adjustment is much swifter during the bull market phase; Dueker (1997) employs a HMM so that switches from periods of low to high volatility explain the evolution of US equities from calm conditions to those that are more like a crisis.
Elliot and Han (2006) use a HMM for the forward-discount. They find evidence against UIP and suggest that a three-regime model fits the data most effectively. However, the study only assesses the GBP-USD exchange rate and other factors that may affect the transition probabilities are not considered. We aim to analyse potential carry-trade profits as arising from one or more regimes.
The model
The first step is to determine whether a one-, two- or three-regime model is the most appropriate. A model with more than one regime is often called a mixture model as the population of potential carry-trade returns are assumed to come from two or more unobserved sub-populations. In this case, the carry-trade returns are observable and are used to identify the underlying exchange rate regime.
The HMM has three components: [pi],A,B:
* the prior model: P([S.sub.1] = n|[[theta].sub.prior]) (n)
* the transition model: P([S.sub.t]|[S.sub.t-1], [[theta].sub.trans]) (A)
* the response model: P([Y.sub.t]|[S.sub.t], [[theta].sub.resp]) (B)
The prior or initial state probabilities give the probability that the system starts in a particular regime; the transition model is the probability of moving from one financial state to another; the response model is the relationship between the observed potential carry-returns and the unobserved financial regime.
There are n states or regimes; [Y.sub.t] are the observed potential carry-trade returns; and [[theta].sub.prior], [[theta].sub.trans] and [[theta].sub.resp] are the parameters of the prior, transition and response models, respectively. The unobserved financial regimes are modelled as a Markov chain that determines the probability of switching between two regimes. The carry-trade returns are affected by the underlying regime and are used to estimate the probability of being in a particular regime. The starting point of the system is given by,
P([S.sub.1] = 1),...P([S.sub.1] = N) (9)
as the probability of being in one of N regimes, and the state transition matrix for a two-state system is:
[mathematical expression not reproducible] (10)
Each element of the matrix shows the probability of being in a particular regime given the previous regime. This is a first-order Markov model. The transition probabilities depend only on the previous state. This seems to be a reasonable assumption in most circumstances. However, to assess whether the risk of a financial crisis is increased by the length of the period of stability, it would be necessary to have a higher-order Markov chain, increasing the memory of the system and the computational complexity. In that case, an alternative method would be more appropriate.
Estimation of the parameters
Estimating the HMM involves determining the most likely values for the three sets of parameters in the model. This estimation is done by maximum likelihood. As a consequence of the Markov assumption, this is a problem that can be solved with the expectation-maximisation (EM) algorithm. See Dempster et al. (1977) and Hamilton (1989) as well as Visser and Speekenbrink (2010) for full details of the procedure. This is a numerical optimisation. There are two steps. First the expectation step will iterate forward from the starting point using prior estimates of the three sets of parameter values to make an initial assessment of the probability of observing each hidden regime given the model parameters. The number of regimes is given. Whether the number of regimes is appropriate will be determined using the log-likelihood ratio and other information criteria. The prior estimates of the parameters can either be drawn randomly or they can be determined by some previous information. (2) In this way, the most likely unobserved regime for each period can be calculated. A variant of the EM algorithm called the forward-backward. or Baum-Welch algorithm as presented by Baum et al. (1970) is used. The Baum-Welch algorithm will find the parameters that maximise the probability of observing the sequence of carry-trade returns.
For the dependent mixture model, the joint likelihood of observation [Y.sub.1:T] and the latent state [S.sub.1:T] given the model parameters is
[mathematical expression not reproducible] (11)
where [[pi].sub.i] is the initial probability of each state; [a.sub.i,j] = P([S.sub.t+1] = j|[S.sub.t] = i is the transition probability; and [mathematical expression not reproducible] is the probability of being in a particular state given the observed carry-trade return, [b.sub.j] = P([Y.sub.t]|[S.sub.t] = j).
Secondly, the maximisation step then updates the most likely values for the three sets of parameters based on the state sequence that has just been identified. Therefore, the probabilities of starting in a particular regime (n) come from the estimates just used to assess the most likely regime in each period; the transition matrix (A) is estimated from the given sequence; and the factor weights for the response model (B) are also updated. For the expectations part of the iteration, the states are replaced by their expected value given the parameters of the models ([theta]).
The estimation process then iterates back and forwards between the expectation and maximisation steps until the log-likelihood of the
given parameters reaches a peak or the degree of improvement falls below a threshold. It is possible to reach a local maximum, so it is usually advisable to run several iterations with different starting values. That has not been done in this case as a seed has been set for the randomisation process in the interest of reproducibility.
ANALYSIS OF RESULTS
Data
The data to be used are a sample of potential carry-trade investments in CEE countries using a variety of funding currencies that have been compiled from exchange rate and interest rate data for the period from January 2000 to December 2013. The exchange rates are presented in Table 1. The data are taken from the IMF International Financial Statistics (IFS).
The funding currencies are those that have been identified by Baele et al. (2013). They are the euro, the US dollar, the Swiss franc and the Japanese yen. A set of potential carry-trade profits are calculated from the exchange rate and interest rate data using a small modification of the method proposed by Brunnermeier et al. (2008),
[p.sub.t] = [[i.sup.*.sub.t] - [i.sub.t]]/[DELTA][s.sub.t] (12)
where [i.sup.*.sub.t] is the investment currency, [i.sub.t] is the funding currency, [DELTA][s.sub.t] is the change in the exchange rate, and [p.sub.t] is the gross profit for potential carrytrades without transaction costs or adjustment for risk. Burnside et al. (2011) construct a similar series for a panel of 10 exchange rates and find a very small effect from plausible transaction costs and Sharpe ratios that compare favourably with equity markets. One-month and three-month positions are calculated. Only the one-month results are presented as the outcomes do not differ significantly.
Table 2 shows the descriptive statistics for each potential carry-trade profit series. This is Model One with only one regime. The mean is the annualised potential profits for each exchange rate when funded in euro. When this is above one (as it is in all cases), strict UIP does not hold. However, though the monthly Sharpe ratios are all above one and this conventional risk-adjusted return is above that of a passive investment in the S&P 500 US equity index for the same period, the significant skews from these potential carry-trade profits (standing more than two standard errors beyond zero) and the fact that in all cases outside Bulgaria maximum losses outweigh maximum gains, indicate that there is some risk here that is not fully captured by conventional measures like standard deviation. The data also suggest that the Czech Republic is a special case as the potential carry-trade returns are more normally distributed with less skew and kurtosis. The implication is that this is less of a carry-trade currency. That may be due to the level of financial development.
Model comparison
Initially, there are three models that are applied to each of the carry-trade-profit series.
* Model One (M1) is a standard linear model [p.sub.t] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[epsilon].sub.t] where [p.sub.t] is the carry-trade-profit series, [[beta].sub.0] is the intercept and [[epsilon].sub.t] is the variation around that level. It provides a mean and standard deviation for the potential carry-trade-profit for the whole period. These are the figures presented in Table 2.
* Model Two (M2) is a standard linear model with two regimes [p.sub.t] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.0] [S.sub.n] + [epsilon], n = 1,2; therefore, a mean and a standard deviation of the potential carry-trade profits for each of the two regimes are produced. The mean and standard deviation of the potential carry-trade profits for each regime are presented in Table 4.
* Model Three (M3) is a standard linear model with three regimes [p.sub.t] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.0][S.sub.n] + s, n = 1,2,3 average and standard deviations are retrieved for three different regimes.
The models are compared using the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) and the log-likelihood ratios (LLR) adjusted for the number of parameters estimated. Table 3 summarises the performance of the three base models using these criteria. The models here are tested using the euro as the funding currency. Results for other funding currencies are very similar and are therefore not reported. A comparison of the mean and variance for the two-regime response models for different funding units is presented in Table 4.
Table 3 compares the three fundamental models with 1, 2 and 3 regimes. They are called Model One (Ml), Model Two (M2) and Model Three (M3), respectively. The aim is to find the number of regimes that provide the best fit for each potential carry-trade profit series. The first three data columns of Table 3 report the AIC for each of the three base models, respectively. The next six columns show the log-likelihood ratio test statistic and the p value for a comparison of Model Two (M2) to Model One (Ml), Model Three (M3) to Model One (Ml) and Model Three (M3) to Model Two (M2), respectively. The null is that the more sophisticated or complex model (two regime rather than one for example) does not improve the explanatory power by more than would be expected with the additional variables. The p value is based on the Chi-squared distribution with degrees of freedom equal to the number of restrictions. The final column combines the two tests to present the model that appears to fit the data most effectively.
As can be seen, the two-regime model is superior to the base model with one regime and the three-regime model for all exchange rates. This indicates that the evolution of potential carry-trade profits is more easily explained as being driven by two regimes than either one or three. This provides support for the notion that the forward-discount puzzle may be explained with reference to a crash risk that is one of the two regimes. Further investigation of the potential carry-trade profits in these two regimes shows that UIP holds during one regime and not in the other. One exception here is the Czech Republic where the two-regime model (M2) provides only modest improvement over the one regime model (M2). The Czech Republic may be better assessed with just a single regime. This case will be investigated further below.
Table 4 presents the estimated response (mean and standard deviation) for each of the two-regime models. The regime with the highest mean is labelled stable. In all cases, this is also the regime with the smallest standard deviation. This is not imposed. It is certainly possible that the regime with the highest mean could also have the highest standard deviation. However, this does not happen for any of the exchange rates under any of the funding regimes. The other regime is labelled crash. The results are encouraging for the hypothesis that potential carry-trade profits are best modelled as two regimes where one of them is considered the period of calm where carry positions are built and the other is considered the period of crisis where carry-trade positions will be cut back. In the first case, the ratio [p.sub.t] should be above one. This is equivalent to the estimated value of [[beta].sub.1] in Eq. 6 being below one. The period labelled calm should also be expected to have smaller standard deviation and less risk because exchange rate conditions are expected to be calm when carry-trade positions can be built. The crisis period should have a mean of less than one and a larger standard deviation to reflect the increased risk that is being taken in this regime. This is when the crash risk happens. The results further support the assertion that potential carry-trade profits are partly a compensation for taking crash risk and that this crash risk is part of the explanation for the forward-discount puzzle. UIP does not hold on average in either regime. Potential carry-trade profits during the calm period are often wiped out in the crash.
There are two other things to note. First, the funding currency that is selected does not make much difference. In no case does the basic result change when different funding currencies are applied. The final column of Table 4 shows the average mean and standard deviation for each regime for each funding currency. They are very similar. As a consequence, the rest of the results that are presented are based on euro-funding. Secondly, the results for the Czech Republic support the view that one regime may be a better way to model the data. Though two regimes can be estimated, the distribution of the potential carry-trade profits does not differ much between the two. It is not a natural carry-trade currency.
The other interesting component is the transition matrix that determines the probability of switching from one regime to another. The most important of these elements is the probability that a period of stability or calm will move to one of crisis. The other item of interest is how likely it is that the crisis persists once it starts. (3) Table 5 provides this information. The probability that a period of calm will turn into a period of crisis ranges from just one per cent in the Czech Republic to as much as fifty per cent in Croatia. Once a crisis has started, it persists for a while. In all cases, this is estimated at between 75 and 95%.
These transition probabilities tell us something about the risk that a particular exchange rate and currency will suffer a foreign exchange crisis. In that way, the probabilities can be used as a risk assessment to quantify how vulnerable a country is to an exchange rate shock. The figures evolve over time, so it is possible to understand how country risk has improved or deteriorated. It would also be possible to use these figures to assess the importance of other risk factors such as exchange rate regime, central bank arrangements and political system.
It is also possible to look at the evolution of most likely regimes over time. Figure 1 shows the potential carry-trade profits and the two regimes for Poland. It is clear that the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) is the main regime change that takes place. There are also a number of smaller mini-crises that are also evident in the turmoil after the GFC. The period of crisis last from 2007 to 2010.
EXOGENOUS INFLUENCES ON REGIME SWITCHING PROBABILITIES
Periods of foreign exchange crisis are generally referred to as sudden stops. See Dornbusch and Werner (1995), Calvo (1998) and Krugman (2000) for more details. Calvo defines the sudden stop as net capital flows moving two standard deviations below their mean level and subsequently returning to within one standard deviation of that point. There are a number of factors that may influence capital flows and exchange rate stability. Exchange rate crisis can be caused by domestic or international factors. Baele et al. (2013) find that exogenous factors that cause sudden stops and flight-to-safety of hard currencies are relatively rare events. Their study of 23 countries discovers that most of the events are country specific. They characterise only 25% of the events as global. Nonetheless, exogenous international effects are the focus here and these are the cases where a global increase in risk aversion causes a capital retreat from emerging economies and a shift towards what are perceived to be safe and stable assets. The sudden stop for the countries is the crash risk for the investors.
Consistent with the evidence of an interplay between monetary policy and international risk, and between domestic and international factors, Ahmed and Zlate (2014) show that economic growth, interest rate differentials and the level of global risk appetite are all important determinants of private capital flows to emerging markets. They also suggest that capital flows have been more sensitive to interest rate differentials since the financial crisis of 2007-2008. There is also some evidence that US quantitative easing has affected capital flows to emerging economies. Funds flow from the US Federal Reserve into high-yielding assets in emerging economies.
Groen and Peck (2014) consider the effect of changes in global risk aversion on the carry-trade. They find that the initial signal from the US central bank in Fed Chairman Bernanke's May 22 2013 testimony to Congress coincide with an increase in global risk aversion which affected global asset prices. By identifying the performance of exchange rates without a change in risk aversion, they suggest that nearly half of the depreciation of a basket of 45 carry-trade currencies with the largest one-month interest rate relative to a basket of the US dollar and other equally low-rate currencies is explained by this increased risk aversion. Nearly all the decline in Emerging market equities is attributable to the increase in risk aversion.
Klemm et al. (2014) use a panel vector autoregression (VAR) method to identify the influence of US monetary policy since 1990 on capital flows to 38 emerging economies, finding evidence that the end to Federal Reserve purchase of government bonds under the quantitative easing programme, while not necessarily leading to capital outflow, could generate new risk premium shocks with investors requiring a higher rate of return and therefore lower asset prices.
Additional models
This section will examine whether exogenous factors influence the potential profitability of the carry-trade or the probability of switching from a regime of foreign exchange calm to one of crisis. The two exogenous forces are to be tested are international risk aversion and US interest rates. Risk aversion is measured with the VIX index while US interest rate is measured as the 3-month US dollar deposit. (4)
These external forces could affect foreign exchange conditions and the carry-trade in two ways: they could have a direct linear influence on rates or they could influence the probability of switching from one regime to another. In the first case, they could be added as an explanatory variable to the simple linear response model. For example,
[y.sub.t] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1] + [Z.sub.t] + [epsilon] (13)
where [y.sub.t] is the carry-trade return and [Z.sub.t] is the exogenous influence on financial stability (either international risk aversion or US interest rates). This is Model Four (M4) with two versions a and b to signify the effect of risk aversion and US interest rates, respectively.
In the second case, the exogenous force may influence the transition probabilities using a multinomial logistic regression. For the transition model (A),
[a.sub.ij](t) = P([S.sub.t] = j|[S.sub.t-1] = i,z) (14)
where [a.sub.ij](f) is the probability that the system will be in state i at time t when it was in state j in the previous period and covariate z takes a particular value at time t. For a two-regime model, the estimation that is carried out is
log([a.sub.t,n=2])/[a.sub.t-1,n=1] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1][z.sub.t] (15)
State 1 is the baseline category, so coefficients are set to zero for that state, and the model estimates the relationship between the covariate and probability of switching to the other state.
The logistic function used for this is
[mathematical expression not reproducible] (16)
giving the estimated probability of being in the particular state conditional on having been in a particular state in the previous period and conditional on the exogenous variable being at a particular level. See Agresti (2014, pp. 174-175) for more details. This is Model Five (M5). There are also two versions of this model (a and b) that will denote whether the probability of switching from one state to the other is conditional on risk aversion or US interest rates.
Table 6 compares models M4a and M5a against models Ml and M2. Models 4a and 5a use the VIX as a measure of international risk aversion as an explanatory variable (M4a Eq. 13) or as conditioning for the transition probability matrix (M5a Eq. 16). Model One (Ml) is the base model with one regime. There are three criteria used to judge the preferred model: the AIC, log-likelihood ratios and simple linear regression of the additional exogenous explanatory variable. Columns 1-4 report the AIC for the Ml, M4a, M2 and M5a models, respectively. Columns 5 and 6 report, respectively, the log-likelihood ratio test statistic and the p value for Model 5a relative to Model 4a; Columns 7 and 8 do the same for the comparison of Model 5a over Model 2. Columns 9 and 10 report the t-statistic and p value of a line regression of the potential carry-trade profits on a constant and the VIX index and the p value. This is Eq. 13 and the estimate is [[beta].sub.1]. Column 11 identifies the model that is most appropriate for each series according to these criteria.
Model 5 is the preferred model in most cases. This is important as it indicates that not only are the potential carry-trade profits best explained by a two-regime model but also that this model is generally improved when the probability of switching from a state of calm to one of crash is conditional on international risk aversion. It suggests that the forward-discount puzzle is at least partly explained as a compensation for taking risk and that this is most likely related to the risk that international risk aversion rises and causes an exit from risky assets like carry positions. This is the crash that characterises exchange rate crisis. For Poland, there is a little uncertainty about whether Model Two or Model Five is better fit for the data. As will be discussed below, it seems that this is because exogenous factors do not have such a major influence on Poland. For Russia and Turkey, while it appears that the level of international risk aversion is best used explaining the probability of switching from one regime to another rather than as an explanation of the level of carry-trade profits, it also appears that the simple two-regime model is more harmonious with the data in these cases. That may be because currency crises here are more influenced by domestic factors.
Table 7 provides more detail about Model 5. The changes in the VIX index are normalised to one standard deviation and the base probability of moving from the calm regime when there is a good chance of achieving carry-trade profits to one of foreign exchange crisis is recorded at various levels of international risk aversion. The average level of international risk aversion (as recorded by the VIX index) is the central column labelled Mean. The probability of switching from a regime of calm to one of crisis is then recorded for one, two and three standard deviations above and below this mean. These are in columns 6, 7 and 8, and 2, 3 and 4, respectively. For example, for HUF there is an eight per cent probability of switching from a period of calm to a period of crisis when the VIX is at its average level. This increases to just under 24% when the VIX is one standard deviation above the mean and reaches nearly eighty per cent at three standard deviations above the mean.
Table 7 also gives the best summary of the effect of international factors on the possibility of a financial crisis. The central column shows that when risk aversion is at an average level, the probability of a crash will range from about 8% in Hungary to around 2% in Poland and Romania. The 8% reading for Czech Republic, considered one of the pillars of stability in the region, is a little surprising. We have already noted that the Czech Republic appears to be a special case. This is probably a function of the analysis ending in 2013. The probability of facing a financial shock increases quite sharply as international risk aversion rises above its average level: at two standard deviations, it indicates that there is a 50% chance of a financial shock in Hungary and the Czech Republic (again surprising) and a 28% chance in Poland, Romania and Croatia. However, as has been seen above, the CZK does not appear to be a natural carry-trade currency.
Table 8 shows the conditional-transition model that is based on 1-month US interest rates. This would be Model Five (M5b). There are only a few countries where the model works. With Poland, the results are contrary to expectations. As US interest rates move above average levels, the risk of moving from a calm to crisis exchange rate regime is reduced. This is probably a result of the limited span of data that are available, the condition that US interest rates were generally falling in the period together with the fact that US rate cuts often follow an international financial crisis. The causation may be reversed: reductions in US interest rates follow international currency crisis, but the monthly data are unable to untangle the ordering. Romania and Russia are more conventional and show modest increase in vulnerability from increased US interest rates on the risk of suffering a financial shock.
A similar analysis was carried out with the TED spread. This is the spread between tbills and eurodollar rates and is used to capture banking credit risk. There is no case where the TED spread provides any improvement in the standard two-regime model. Again, the failure may be a consequence of the limited data span. There is just one episode where there was a significant increase in the spread (around the time of the Lehman Brothers' bankruptcy in October 2008 where the spread reached 335bp).
CONCLUSIONS
In this paper, we have looked at the way that the carry-trade can be modelled as a two-regime system that switches from what can be called a period of calm to one of crisis with a simple Markov model. In all the cases assessed here, the two-regime model provides a better fit for the data than a model with either one or three regimes. We identify the risk that each country will move from a position of calm to one of crisis. We also show that the probability of switching from a period of calm to a period of crisis is affected by exogenous factors like the level of international risk aversion.
The method can be used to assess country risk and the contribution of various factors (such as exchange rate regime) to that risk. This way of looking at the UIP puzzle also adds to the evidence that the returns to the carry-trade are at least partly a compensation for taking crash risk. The breakdown in UIP only holds during the regime that can be described as calm. In the other regime, the risk of large losses can potentially overwhelm all the gains that were achieved during the period of calm. These losses could potentially be sufficient to destroy the investor.
The use of the first-order Markov model does mean that the series has a very short memory and the time spent in a condition of calm does not affect the probability of shifting to an exchange rate crisis. However, if the intensity of the exchange rate shock is related to the amount of time that system has been in a calm state, it is possible that three states would be a more reasonable model. That model is rejected here. However, that may be because there are insufficient data for it to be calibrated effectively.
The study of CEE countries is affected by the relative lack of data and the importance of the GFC. Extending the examination to assess the way that external factors can influence the probability of switching from a period of calm to one of crisis reveals some unusual results. External factors do not seem to have a major influence on the probability of switching to an unstable foreign exchange regime in Poland. This seems to be a consequence of the modest reaction to the GFC that has been experienced. The greater vulnerability of the Czech Republic is surprising, but throughout this process it appears that the two-regime model does less well in explaining potential carry-trade profits in for the Czech exchange rate and this may be because in recent years the CZK has been less of a traditional carry-trade currency. It may be evidence of financial sophistication.
REFERENCES
Agresti, A. 2014: Categorical Data Analysis. New York: John Wiley & Sons.
Ahmed, S and Zlate, A. 2014: Capital flows to emerging market economies: A brave new world? Journal of International Money and Finance 48(B): 221-248.
Bacchetta, P and van Wincoop, E. 2012: Modeling exchange rates with incomplete information, in J. James, 1. Marsh and L. Sarno, eds, 'Handbook of Exchange Rates', Wiley.
Baele, L, Bekaert, G, Inghelbrecht, K and Wei, M. 2013: Flights to safety, NBER Working Paper (19095).
Bansal, R and Dahlquist, M. 1999: The forward premium puzzle: different tales from developed and emerging economies, Journal of International Economics 51(1): 115-144.
Baum, LE, Petrie, T, Soules, G and Weiss, N. 1970: A maximization technique occuring in the statistical analysis of probabilistic functions of Markov chains. The Annals of Mathematical Statistics 41(1): 164-171.
Brunnermeier, M, Nagel, S and Pedersen, L. 2008: Carry trades and currency crashes. NBER Working Papers (14473).
Brunnermeier, M and Pedersen, L. 2009: Market liquidity and funding liquidity. Review of Financial Studies 22(6): 2201-2238.
Burnside, C, Eichenbaum, M, Kleshchelski, I and Rebelo, S. 2011: Do peso prolbems explain the returns to the carry trade? The Review of Financial Studies 24: 853-891.
Calvo, GA. 1998: Capital flows and capital-market crises : the simple economics of sudden stops. Journal of Applied Economcs 1(1): 34-54.
Canova, F and Marrinan, J. 1993: Profits, risk and uncertainty in foreign exchange markets. Journal of Monetary Economics 32: 259-286.
Chicago Board of Trade. 2009: The VIX white paper. URL: http://www.cboe.com/micro/vix/ vixwhite.pdf.
Chinn, M and Meredith, G. 2004: Monetary policy and long-horizon uncovered interest parity. IMF Staff Papers 51: 409-430.
Demeterfi, K, Derman, E, Kamal, M and Zou, J. 1999: More than you ever wanted to know about volatility swaps. Goldman Sachs Quantitative Strategies Research Notes.
Dempster, AP, Laird, NM and Rubin, DB. 1977: Maximum likelihood from incomplete data via the em algorithm. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series B (Methodological) 39(1): 1-38.
Diamond, RV. 2012. Vix as a variance swap. URL: http://ssrn.com/abstract = 2030292.
Dornbusch, R and Werner, A. 1995: Currenc crises and collapses. Brookings Papers in Economic Activity 1995(2): 219-293.
Dueker, MJ. 1997: Markov switching in GARCH processes and mean-reverting stock-market volatility. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 15(1): 26-34.
Elliot, RJ and Han, B. 2006: A hidden markov approach to the forward premium puzzle. International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance 9: 1009-1020.
Engel, C. 1996: The forward discount anomaly and the risk premium: A survey of recent evidence. Journal of Empirical Finance 3(2): 123-192.
Engel, C. 2014: Exchange rates and interest parity. In Gopinath G, Helpman E and Rogoff K (eds). Handbook of International Economics, 1 edn, Vol. 4, Elsevier, chapter 8, pp. 453-522.
Fama, E. 1984: Forward and spot exchange rates. Journal of Monetary Economics 14: 319-338.
Froot, K. 1990: Short rates and expected asset returns. NBER Working Paper (3247).
Groen, J and Peck, R. 2014: Risk aversion, global asset prices, and Fed tightening signals. URL: http://libertystreeteconomics.newyorkfed.org/2014/03/risk-aversion-global-asset-prices-andfed-tightening-signals-.html.
Hamilton, JD. 1988: Rational-expectations econometric analysis of changes in regime: An investigation of the term structure of interest rates. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 12(2): 385-423.
Hamilton, JD. 1989: A new approach to the economic analysis of nonstationary time series and the business cycle. Econometrica 52(2): 357-384.
Hayward, R. 2013: Towards a model of speculation in the foreign exchange market, Ph.D. thesis, University of Brighton Business School.
Hayward, R and Holscher, J. 2014: U1P, the carry trade and Minsky's financial instability hypothesis in the CEE and CIS. In: J. Holscher, (ed). 'Poland and the Eurozone', Studies in economic transition, Palgrave, chapter 7, pp. 111-138.
Hodrick, R. 1987: The Empirical Evidence on the Efficiency of Forward and Futures Foreign Exchange Markets, Harwood, New York.
IMF 2009: Classification of exchange rate arrangements and monetary policy frameworks. URL: http://www.imf.org/external/NP/mfd/er/index.aspx.
Jurek, JW. 2014: Crash-neutral currency carry trades. Journal of Financial Economics 113: 325-347.
Klemm, A, Meier, A and Sosa, S. 2014: Taper tantrum or tedium: How will the normalization of U.S. monetary policy affect Latin-America and the Caribbean? In: IMF: Regional Economic Outlook: Western Hemisphere--Rising Challenges, pp. 37-46.
Krugman, P. ed. 2000: Currency Crises, University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
McCallum, BT. 1994: A reconsideration of the uncovered interest parity relationship. Journal of Monetary Economics 33: 105-132.
Roll, R and Yan, S. 2000: An explanation of the forward premium puzzle. European Financial Management 6(2): 121-148.
Schaller, H and Norden, SV. 1997: Regime switching in stock market returns. Applied Financial Economics 7(2): 177-191.
Spronk, R, Vershoor, WF and Zwinkels, RC. 2013: Carry trade and foreign exchange rate puzzles. European Economic Review 60: 17-31.
Visser, I and Speekenbrink, M. 2010: depmixS4: An R package for hidden Markov models. Journal of Statistical Software 36(7): 1-21. URL: http://www.jstatsoft.org/v36/i07/.
(1) Since the global financial crisis, there is increased evidence that this is not the case as credit and regulatory frictions have become more prominent.
(2) In this case, the parameters are drawn randomly. However, it would be possible to make initial estimates of the response model from Hayward (2013) using the estimates of the carry-trade returns that are identified.
(3) The other two components (remaining in the calm regime and switching from a period of crisis to one of calm) can be calculated from these transition probabilities.
(4) The VIX is an index of implied volatility on options from the S&P 500 index. It is commonly used as a measure of international risk aversion as it signals increased demand by fund managers for option protection of their equity portfolio. See Chicago Board of Trade (2009), Demeterfi (1999) and Diamond (2012) for fuller details.
ROB HAYWARD (1) & JENS HOLSCHER (2)
(1) University of Brighton Business School, Lewes Road, Brighton BN2 4AT, UK. E-mail: rh49@brighton.ac.uk
(2) Executive Business Centre, Bournemouth University, 89 Holdenhurst Road, Bournemouth BH8 8EB, UK.
Caption: Figure 1: PLN Carry-trade probabilities
Table 1: Countries, ISO codes and exchange rate arrangements Country ISO code Exchange rate arrangement Bulgaria BGN Currency board Czech Republic CZK Float Croatia HRK Fixed peg Hungary HUF Float Poland PLN Float Romania RON Managed float Russia RUB Fixed peg Ukraine UAH Managed float Turkey TRY Float The table shows the exchange rates that are assessed with the ISO codes that are used from this point onwards in the paper and the relevant exchange rate regime. The exchange rate regime is taken from the IMF Classification of Exchange Rate Arrangements and Monetary Policy Frameworks IMF (2009). In many cases, there are changes to the arrangements; when that happens, the summary here reflects the stance at the end of the period. For more details, see Hayward and Holscher (2014). Table 2: Descriptive statistics of potential carry-trade profits HUF PLN CZK RON RUB Count 167 167 167 167 167 Mean 12.80 12.41 10.07 11.94 7.21 Sharpe 1.83 1.88 1.56 1.99 1.50 Median 21.52 13.75 9.32 17.42 9.58 StDev 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.06 0.05 Skew -0.51 -0.57 -0.21 -0.33 -0.93 SES 0.19 0.19 0.19 0.19 0.19 Kurt 1.64 1.40 0.44 1.36 3.37 SEK 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99 Max 20.41 18.61 18.09 17.26 16.02 Min -25.49 -21.84 -19.56 -20.75 -21.11 BGN UAH HRK TRY SPY Count 167 167 159 166 167 Mean 8.09 7.84 10.73 13.56 5.19 Sharpe 1.36 1.89 1.74 2.10 1.28 Median 7.64 10.06 12.02 16.85 8.75 StDev 0.06 0.04 0.06 0.07 0.05 Skew -0.02 -1.45 -0.16 -0.67 -0.46 SES 0.19 0.19 0.19 0.19 0.19 Kurt 1.02 7.37 0.90 2.60 0.66 SEK 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99 Max 21.58 14.76 17.66 18.64 11.49 Min -18.88 -21.93 -19.03 -26.68 -16.04 The table shows the descriptive statistics for the calculated potential carry-trade profits for each exchange rate (identified by ISO code) plus a comparison with a passive investment in the S&P 500, recorded in the final column and measured by the SPY Exchange traded fund. Count is the number of observations; Mean is the annualised return; Sharpe is the monthly Sharpe ratio, assuming a risk-free rate of zero; Median is the median annualised return; StDev is the standard deviation of returns; Skew is the measure of Skewness of the return distribution; SES is the standard error of skewness so that a skewness that is twice this size could be considered to be statistically significant at the 5% level; Kurt is the measure of excess kurtosis; SEK is the standard error of kurtosis; Max is the maximum annualised return; Min is the minimum annualised return. Table 3: Comparison of models AIC(M1) ACI(M2) AIC(M3) LLR21 LLR21p HUF -404.69 -416.94 -407.23 22.25 0.0005 PLN -423.98 -437.62 -428.82 23.65 0.0003 CZK -427.23 -427.37 -415.61 10.14 0.0714 RON -456.02 -474.81 -464.39 28.79 0.0000 RUB -523.18 -567.77 -559.95 54.59 0.0000 BGN -451.98 -454.32 -443.21 12.34 0.0305 UAH -572.87 -643.36 -636.39 80.49 0.0000 HRK -431.55 -433.37 -426.58 11.82 0.0373 TRY -431.05 -441.00 -432.58 19.95 0.0013 LLR31 LLR31p LLR32 LLR32p Preferred HUF 26.50 0.0090 4.30 0.7459 M2 PLN 28.80 0.0042 5.20 0.6357 M2 CZK 12.40 0.4155 2.20 0.9451 M1 or M2 RON 32.40 0.0012 3.60 0.8264 M2 RUB 60.80 0.0000 6.20 0.5188 M2 BGN 15.20 0.2291 2.90 0.8945 M2 UAH 87.50 0.0000 7.00 0.4257 M2 HRK 19.00 0.0877 7.20 0.4068 M2 TRY 25.50 0.0125 5.60 0.5895 M2 The table shows how well the potential carry-trade profit data for each exchange rate fits each of the three main models. Model One (M1) is the base model with just one regime, Model Two (M2) is the model with 2 regimes. Model Three (M3) is the model with 3 regimes. The first three data columns show the Akaike Information index (AIC) for each model. The lowest number is the best fit. The next six columns are paired with a the log-likelihood ratio test statistics that compares the two named and nested models and a p value for the [chi square] probability with degrees of freedom equal to the number of parameter constraints of the base model that the log-likelihood ratio is different from one. For example, LLR21 is the log-likelihood ratio of Model One to Model Two and LLR21p is the probability value. In column four of the first row, the LLR21 indicates that the log-likelihood ratio of a two regime to one regime model for the Hungarian forint is 22.25 and in column five the p value shows that the two-regime model is a significant improvement over the base model. The final column summarises the information for each row by selecting the regime model that best explains the explains the data. Table 4: Mean and standard deviation of 2 regime model Funding Regime HUF PLN CZK EUR Stable Mean 1.0165 1.0173 1.0129 St-Dev 0.0519 0.0486 0.0542 Crash Mean 0.9905 0.9862 0.9963 S-Dev 0.1085 0.1026 0.0886 USD Stable Mean 1.0103 1.0123 1.0072 S-Dev 0.0307 0.0297 0.0305 Crash Mean 0.9925 0.9845 0.9983 S-Dev 0.0707 0.0641 0.0493 CHF Stable Mean 1.0052 1.0097 1.0040 S-Dev 0.0181 0.0235 0.0161 Crash Mean 0.9994 0.9838 0.9934 S-Dev 0.0477 0.0459 0.0380 JPY Stable Mean 1.0149 1.0157 1.0125 S-Dev 0.0348 0.0359 0.0241 Crash Mean 0.9843 0.9727 1.0012 S-Dev 0.0767 0.0764 0.0525 Funding Regime RON RUB TRY EUR Stable Mean 1.0150 1.0098 1.0151 St-Dev 0.0433 0.0310 0.0460 Crash Mean 0.9969 0.9962 0.9969 S-Dev 0.0878 0.0779 0.1028 USD Stable Mean 1.0091 1.0044 1.0087 S-Dev 0.0080 0.0095 0.0314 Crash Mean 1.0052 1.0004 1.0034 S-Dev 0.0389 0.0407 0.0792 CHF Stable Mean 1.0085 1.0033 1.0099 S-Dev 0.0179 0.0234 0.0313 Crash Mean 0.9959 0.9373 0.9952 S-Dev 0.0387 0.0592 0.0792 JPY Stable Mean 1.0149 1.0074 1.0111 S-Dev 0.0291 0.0226 0.0401 Crash Mean 0.9972 0.9983 1.0061 S-Dev 0.0580 0.0628 0.0889 Funding Regime BGN UAH EUR Stable Mean 1.0075 1.0094 St-Dev 0.0381 0.0295 Crash Mean 1.0053 0.9673 S-Dev 0.0826 0.1116 USD Stable Mean 1.0041 1.0055 S-Dev 0.0189 0.0078 Crash Mean 1.0016 0.9932 S-Dev 0.0413 0.0635 CHF Stable Mean 1.0012 1.0029 S-Dev 0.0083 0.0307 Crash Mean 0.9958 0.9834 S-Dev 0.0327 0.0900 JPY Stable Mean 1.0092 1.0094 S-Dev 0.0191 0.0307 Crash Mean 1.0002 0.8539 S-Dev 0.0487 0.0667 Funding Regime HRK Mean EUR Stable Mean 1.0091 1.0119 St-Dev 0.0251 0.0446 Crash Mean 1.0082 0.9897 S-Dev 0.0737 0.0958 USD Stable Mean 1.0054 1.0071 S-Dev 0.0187 0.0202 Crash Mean 1.0036 0.9959 S-Dev 0.0390 0.0566 CHF Stable Mean 1.0031 1.0051 S-Dev 0.0116 0.0205 Crash Mean 0.9916 0.9857 S-Dev 0.0384 0.0538 JPY Stable Mean 1.0091 1.0115 S-Dev 0.0210 0.0289 Crash Mean 1.0028 0.9801 S-Dev 0.0493 0.0668 This table outlines the linear response for Model Two (M2) for each of the two regimes for all exchange rates under consideration. Stable is the label given to the regime with the highest mean return. In all cases, this is also the regime with the smallest standard deviation. This is not imposed and it is encouraging as it is consistent with the idea that the potential carry-trade profits in this stable regime are compensation for taking risk of large losses in the crash regime. Results are presented for all four funding currencies. The final column gives the average performance for each funding currency. Table 5: Transition probabilities CZK HRK HUF PLN Calm to crisis 0.01 0.50 0.04 0.04 Remain in crisis 0.97 0.74 0.88 0.87 RON RUB TRY UAH Calm to crisis 0.01 0.01 0.10 0.01 Remain in crisis 0.97 0.98 0.71 0.91 The table shows the transition probabilities for each of the countries. This is the A component described in 'The model' Section and Eq. 10. The first row records the probability that a calm regime will switch to one of currency crisis; the second row shows the probability that once in the regime of currency crisis, the regime will remain in place in the next period. Table 6: VIX covariate model table AIC(M1) ACI(M4a) AIC(M2) AIC(M5a) LLR54 HUF -404.69 -402.70 -416.94 -419.50 28.80 PLN -423.98 -422.03 -437.62 -438.93 28.90 CZK -427.23 -425.25 -427.37 -430.52 17.27 RON -456.02 -454.42 -474.81 -478.07 35.65 RUB -523.18 -449.98 -567.77 -566.68 128.70 BGN -451.98 -449.98 -454.32 -459.55 21.56 UAH -572.87 -571.47 -643.36 -647.67 88.20 HRK -431.55 -429.58 -433.37 -439.42 21.84 TRY -431.05 -429.06 -441.00 -439.26 22.20 LLR54p LLR52 LLR52p Coeff p value Preferred HUF 0.0001 6.56 0.0377 -0.00 0.9529 M5 PLN 0.0001 5.30 0.0705 -0.00 0.8202 M5/2 CZK 0.0083 7.15 0.0280 0.00 0.8935 M5 RON 0.0000 7.26 0.0265 0.00 0.5307 M5 RUB 0.0000 2.92 0.2328 -0.00 0.9833 M2 BGN 0.0015 9.23 0.0099 -0.00 0.9892 M5 UAH 0.0000 8.31 0.0157 0.00 0.4451 M5 HRK 0.0013 10.05 0.0066 -0.00 0.8590 M5 TRY 0.0011 2.26 0.3232 -0.00 0.9575 M2 The table details the comparison of four models. Here Model One (M1) is the base model with one regime; Model Four (M4a) adds the VIX index as a response variable (Eq. 13); Model Two (M2) is the simple response model with two regimes; Model Five (M5a) is the two-regime model with the VIX index providing a logistic covariate of the transition matrix. The first four columns show the Akaike Information index (AIC) for each model. The lowest number is the best fit. The next four columns are paired with a the log-likelihood ratio test statistics that compares the two named and nested models and a p value for the [chi square] probability with degrees of freedom equal to the number of parameter constraints on the base model. The t test is that the log-likelihood ratio is different from one. For example, LLR54 is the log-likelihood ratio of Model Five to Model Four, and LLR54p is the p value. In data column five of the first row, the LLR54 indicates that the log-likelihood ratio of M5 to M4 for the Hungarian forint is 28.80 and in column six the p value shows that the two-regime model is a significant improvement over the base model. The column labelled Coeff is from Model Four. It is the estimate of [[beta].sub.1] from a regression of Eq. 13; p value is the test of the null hypothesis that [[beta].sub.1] is equal to zero. The final column summarises the information for each row with a preferred model. Table 7: Assessing the influence of VIX index on financial risk -3sd -2sd -1sd Mean HUF 0.0020 0.0069 0.0242 0.0807 PLN 0.0004 0.0016 0.0063 0.0242 CZK 0.0020 0.0062 0.0234 0.0770 RON 0.0014 0.0043 0.0131 0.0392 RUB 0.0008 0.0022 0.0065 0.0189 BGN 0.0052 0.0145 0.0403 0.1066 HRK 0.0027 0.0073 0.0194 0.0506 -1sd +2sd +3sd HUF 0.2375 0.5249 0.7967 PLN 0.0887 0.2766 0.6003 CZK 0.2247 0.5019 0.7779 RON 0.1119 0.2799 0.5453 RUB 0.0537 0.1430 0.3291 BGN 0.2533 0.4910 0.7328 HRK 0.1257 0.2793 0.5109 Changes in the VIX index affect the transition probabilities. The VIX index has been scaled so that it has a mean of zero and a standard deviation of one. Therefore, the central column (from the transition matrix) (from the transition matrix) (from the transition matrix) (from the transition matrix) (from the transition matrix) (from the transition matrix) (from the transition matrix) (from the transition matrix) (from the transition matrix) shows the probability that the system will switch from a stable regime to one of crisis when the VIX is at its average level. It also shows how this probability changes as the VIX moves one or more standard deviations above and below this average. For example, for Hungary, there is an 8% chance that the system will switch to a period of crash when the VIX is at its average value. This rises to 24% when the VIX is one standard deviation above average and 52% for 2 standard deviations. Table 8: Assessing the influence of US 1-month interest rate on financial risk -3sd -2sd -1sd PLN 0.6601 0.4110 0.2005 RON 0.0062 0.0106 0.0182 RUB 0.0011 0.0025 0.0056 Mean +1sd +2sd +3sd PLN 0.0827 0.0314 0.0115 0.0042 RON 0.0310 0.0524 0.0871 0.1414 RUB 0.0126 0.0283 0.0620 0.1305 Changes in US 1-month interest rates affect the transition probabilities. The US 1-month interest rate has been scaled so that it has a mean of zero and a standard deviation of one. Therefore, the central column shows the probability that the system will switch from a stable regime to one of crisis when the 1-month interest rate is at its average level. It also shows how this probability changes as the 1-month interest rate moves one or more standard deviations above and below this average. For example, for Romania there is a three per cent chance of moving to a foreign exchange crisis when US interest rates are at their mean level. This rises to 5, 9 and 15% as interest rates move one, two and three standard deviations above average.
![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() | |
Title Annotation: | Symposium Article |
---|---|
Author: | Hayward, Rob; Holscher, Jens |
Publication: | Comparative Economic Studies |
Article Type: | Report |
Date: | Dec 1, 2017 |
Words: | 11061 |
Previous Article: | The Evolving Architecture of Europe: Functioning or Dysfunctional for the Twenty-First Century? |
Next Article: | The Choice of Reforms and Economic System in the Baltic States. |
Topics: |