Printer Friendly

Statements to the Congress.

Thank you for this opportunity to present the Federal Reserve Board's views on reforms to the regulation of the government securities market. Since September, when I last testified before this Committee, staff of the Federal Reserve, the Treasury Department, and the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) have conducted an exhaustive examination of this market, the results of which were released two weeks ago. My prepared remarks will touch upon some of the main conclusions of this report from the particular perspective of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Our perspective differs somewhat from the perspectives of the other agencies contributing to the report because of differences in legislative mandates. The Board of Governors has little direct regulatory authority for the U.S. government securities market.

Although the Board has general oversight responsibility for all Federal Reserve District Banks, it is the District Banks that act as fiscal agents of the Treasury, thus sharing operating responsibility for the market with the Treasury. The SEC's charge is to enforce the securities laws that seek to foster a high degree of fairness in the marketplace. With neither the direct responsibilities of funding the government nor substantial regulatory oversight, the Board of Governors can view this market from a somewhat different vantage point--a policy perspective that allows it to examine these issues in an economywide context.

When we look to the government securities market, we see a market that works as well as any on earth. U.S. government debt is an ideal trading vehicle because it is all closely substitutable and has none of the default risk or idiosyncratic problems of private issues. As a result, market participants, in the aggregate, willingly commit substantial amounts of risk capital and exchange a large volume of securities each day. Positions are large, yet trading skills are so sharply refined that bid-ask spreads are razor thin, a small fraction of the size of spreads in major equity markets.

The government securities market generates widespread macroeconomic benefits. It efficiently absorbs the large quantity of new issues required to finance the deficit. With real-time quotes on a range of instruments, this market serves as the foundation for private market rates and a haven for ready liquidity. Further, this deep and liquid market gives the Federal Reserve a powerful, reliable mechanism for implementing monetary policy.

Nonetheless, the admission of wrongdoing by Salomon Brothers, episodes of price distortions, and other evidence uncovered in our joint study all suggest that this market has faults. It can be improved. The proposals contained in the joint report, along with other reforms announced earlier, constitute a careful, comprehensive modernization of the mechanisms and practices in the government securities market. In our view, implementing these proposals represents a formidable, though feasible, task.

Over the longer term, the most effective force in enhancing market efficiency and reducing the potential for manipulative abuses is the force of competition. And the effect of these proposals is to open up the government securities market to broad-based participation. Automating Treasury auctions; facilitating direct bidding by customers, including nonprimary dealers; implementing a single-price open-auction technique; and reducing the barriers to primary dealer membership--all will serve, in time, to broaden participation in the primary market and in the secondary market for newly issued securities. More depth and breadth in this end of the market should increase efficiency, reduce Treasury financing costs, and lessen the potential for manipulative trading abuses. In addition, the competitive force of broader participation will be reinforced by proposals targeted at manipulative abuse: tighter enforcement of auction rules and enhanced market surveillance by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York to identify potential manipulative episodes that could trigger SEC investigation and Treasury supply management to reopen offerings.

Taken together, these actions should serve to deter manipulative practices and allow quick detection of abuses should they occur. Moreover, they are relatively low-cost, market-based responses that should achieve these benefits without impairing the efficiency and liquidity of this vital market.

Of course, many other alternatives could be considered to combat the potential for abuses in this market. However, the government securities market is too important a national resource and works too well to be put at risk by regulatory change for the sake of change. From the Board of Governors' perspective, a compelling case must be established that the benefits outweigh the costs.

In our view, such a compelling cost-benefit analysis has not been made with respect to proposals to establish a broad-based apparatus of reporting requirements or audit trails in this market. Although increased reporting would deter manipulation and facilitate the investigation of abuses, such systems would impose substantial potential costs on this market. The reporting burden would fall on all traders--the good and the bad-boosting the cost of every trade. While the direct costs of additional recordkeeping might be kept manageable, an indirect cost looms larger. Rather than risk divulging their finances and trading strategies, participants might withdraw from this market, thereby raising the cost of Treasury finance. And, of course, the stakes are high: A tiny increase in Treasury rates aggregates into a very substantial increase in cost to U.S. taxpayers.

Because it might be difficult to resist implementing, even backup authority risks sending a chilling message about the U.S. market to all participants choosing a trading arena in the global marketplace. Moreover, in view of the extensive nature of the other changes proposed in this report, one might question the capacity of this market to absorb, at an acceptable cost, this additional change--the imposition of broad-based reporting requirements for this market. The agencies agree that large position reporting requirements should not be implemented at this time. Rather than risk slipping into this fundamental change through backup authority, the Board of Governors feels it would be a wiser course of action to return to the Congress in the future should such authority appear necessary.

The interagency report provides an alternative to burdensome regulation--a low-cost, marketbased solution to the problem that targets manipulative behavior without impairing the liquidity of this important market. This overall strategy has three basic elements: improved auction mechanisms, enhanced market surveillance, and active supply management.

Although many aspects of the Salomon Brothers admission of wrongdoing and the results of the subsequent investigation cause concern, one is particularly unsettling: Because of the falsification of bids at auctions, the Treasury was the direct counterparty in attempts to manipulate the market. Immediate steps were taken to reduce the risk of a reoccurrence, including tightening the enforcement of auction rules and implementing measures to encourage more direct bidding. Looking forward, automation of the auction process, already under way and expected to be completed by year-end, should efficiently snare any infraction of the rules.

More important still, automation will facilitate consideration of alternative auction techniques. At a minimum, switching to single-price awards from the current multiple-price format should foster greater participation and likely reduce gaming behavior at the auction. But more can be done. Linking bidders directly by a computer network and conducting the auction in real time will expose any would-be manipulator to public scrutiny in time for the competition to react. With the element of surprise gone, the potential return to manipulation should disappear. Thus, the auction of the near future may well be played in the open, on a level field, with sharply defined and easily policed foul lines.

The report also finds that the benefits of enhanced monitoring extend to when-issued and secondary market trading. Manipulative behavior leaves its footprints in market quotes because a shortage of an issue will be evidenced by a yield below that of similar securities and by depressed financing rates. The agencies agreed that the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, with its substantial experience as the operating arm of the Federal Open Market Committee and (along with the other Reserve Banks) as one of the fiscal agents of the Treasury, should have primary responsibility for market surveillance; the Bank, in turn, will provide information to the Treasury, the SEC, and the Board of Governors. The view of the Board of Governors is that rigorous monitoring of the behavior of market rates will expose manipulative behavior without the need to gather the positions of large traders routinely.

Indeed, automation and enhanced market monitoring also present the opportunity to correct a longstanding market misimpression. Although the Federal Reserve Bank of New York has no statutory authority to regulate the primary dealers, many people view the primary dealer system as evidence of some measure of oversight of those firms by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Ongoing automation and enhanced monitoring capabilities will let the Bank move to a more open set of trading relationships, thus disabusing market participants of the notion that the primary dealers have a special status. To further that end, the Bank will eliminate its dealer surveillance unit, showing unambiguously that responsibility rests with the primary regulator. The Bank will also lower the impediments to primary-dealer membership, thereby encouraging a broadening of membership in the primary-dealer system.

The careful monitoring of the market will be made more credible by action: Persistent and large-scale price anomalies consistent with a manipulative squeeze will call forth two sets of policy responses. First, if other evidence (including discussions with market participants) suggests manipulation, then the SEC will begin an investigation to determine if any security laws have been broken. Second, and more immediately, the Treasury will act in the market to narrow those price anomalies, thereby limiting the extent of the market disruption in general and reducing the potential gain if manipulative behavior was the root cause. The Treasury's actions will be effected by either holding a new auction of the sought-after security--a reopening--or through the sale of those securities into the market by the Trading Desk of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York on behalf of the Treasury--a tap issuance. The resulting expansion of supply should slash the manipulator's potential gain, making it unlikely that any one would even try to manipulate the market. Circumstance and experience over time will dictate when an increase in supply will be required and which means of augmenting the issue will be taken.

It is the judgment of the Board of Governors that the reforms that I have outlined--changes in auction mechanisms, active and rigorous monitoring of market rates, and the clear willingness to use relative supplies to punish manipulative behavior--will work to prevent a replay of last year's events. These reforms are fundamental changes in market mechanisms that promise to open this market to broad-based participation while, at the same time, enhancing regulatory surveillance and remedial capabilities. These responses are measured, targeted, and commensurate to the problem at hand and in our view obviate the need to punish many with reporting burdens because of the actions of a few. This strategy also offers flexibility to deal with future problems as they arise. It is perhaps ironic that the most serious abuses in the history of this market--the Salomon Brothers episode--have served as the catalyst for changes that promise substantial long-term benefits. Taken together, these proposals and those already implemented constitute a thorough, thoughtful, and feasible renovation of the government securities market and will result in a healthier, more efficient market for U.S. government securities.
COPYRIGHT 1992 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 1992, Gale Group. All rights reserved. Gale Group is a Thomson Corporation Company.

Article Details
Printer friendly Cite/link Email Feedback
Title Annotation:David W. Mullins Jr. testimony concerning government securities market reform
Publication:Federal Reserve Bulletin
Article Type:Transcript
Date:Apr 1, 1992
Words:1877
Previous Article:Treasury and Federal Reserve foreign exchange options.
Next Article:Statements to the Congress.
Topics:


Related Articles
David W. Mullins Jr.
Statements to the Congress.
Statements to the Congress.
Statements to the Congress.
Statement by David W. Mullins, Jr., Vice Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, before the Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary...
Look who's talking, too.
Linguistics in the courtroom.
The Nation.
CLINTON'S DEEP FEAR REVEALED; NEW TRANSCRIPTS RELEASED.
Congress not likely to act on mold bill until next year. (Capitol Beat).

Terms of use | Copyright © 2016 Farlex, Inc. | Feedback | For webmasters