Printer Friendly

Socio-economic transformations in post-communist countries: Central and Eastern Europe and Russia compared.

Introduction

This article investigates the most recent socio-economic transformations occurring in post-communist countries taken as ex ample the cases of Central and Eastern Europe (2) (CEE) and of the Russian Federation. It also provides a sufficient overview of the new social risks emerging in these transition economies. The investigation is structured around three crucial questions. Section One aims to respond to the question of what kind of systemic problems (from now onwards strukturprobleme (3)) characterize post-communist capitalism(s). Section Two addresses the issue of what kind of social structure is developing, while Section Three deals with the question of what kind of new social risks are emerging.

The reason why finding an adequate response to these questions is crucial depends on three principal factors. Firstly, systemic deficiencies present in the economic environment can greatly influence the social structure of a country. Secondly, these deficiencies contribute, at the same time, to the emergence of specific new social risks. Thirdly, they also determine the subsequent welfare state responses. As it is well known, the transition from communism to capitalism has implied huge social costs in both CEE and in the Russian Federation. GDP dropped severely, many state-owned enterprises collapsed, several million workers lost their jobs, the paternalistic system of social protection was, to a large extent, dismantled, and, as a result, poverty rates and income inequality dramatically increased with a large proportion of the population now living below the poverty threshold (Cerami 2006a, 2006b, 2009; Cook 2007; Manning and Tikhonova 2009).

An enormous transformation, however, occurred not only in the economic sphere, but also in the relationship between the state, the market and the society. In the immediate aftermath of 1989, new ideas, interests and institutions had to be quickly introduced (4). A new social contract, no longer based on one-party rule and full-employment, had to be established with the citizens, whereas, in order to put the new social contract in action, new feasible institutions and interests had to be developed. This implied a process of functional, distributive, normative and institutional recalibration (5) in which the functional prerogatives, distributive objectives, normative foundations and institutional structures of these communist systems had to be adjusted to the post-communist environment. As highlighted by several authors, communist ruins represented, in this context, the main institutional material in which the new societies could be built (Offe 1996; Crawford and Lijphardt 1997; Stark and Bruszt 1998; Ekiert 2003). In other words, a recombinant transformation of ideas, interests and institutions took place (Cerami forthcoming).

This study is based on the assumption that the strutkturprobleme of contemporary capitalism(s), changes in social structure and emergence of new social risks are not unrelated issues, but elements strictly linked together. The main hypothesis, which will then be tested in the following sections, is that due to more drastic systemic structural changes occurring in post-communist societies, more intense and more diversified strukturprobleme are taking place in transition economies than those present in the West. These are resulting in faster changes in social structure as well as the emergence of broader new social risks types and groups. If this is the case, then post-communist welfare states are in front of a double burden of responsibilities. On the one hand, they will be called to ensure citizens both against old and new social risks, as Western welfare states are also required to do, while, on the other hand, they will also be forced to intensify their efforts in order to deal with the more severe problems stemming from the transition.

What kind of Strukturprobleme Characterize Post-Communist Capitalism(s)?

This section aims to improve understanding of the main strukturprobleme of post-communist capitalism(s). On the basis of Claus Offe's reflections (Offe 1973, 2006), the strukturprobleme of modern capitalism(s) may involve three distinct dimensions: political, economic, and societal (6). In the political dimension, the main strukturprobleme of contemporary capitalism(s) concern the system-stabilizing capacity of political institutions, in the economic dimension, they concern the economic capacity and performance of firms and markets, while, in the societal dimension, they concern the social integration capacity of political, economic and societal institutions. For the sake of brevity, only the key elements for each distinct dimension will be highlighted. What is important here to note is that even though no country is immune to systemic problems, in the specific case of transition economies, due to the still uncompleted process of consolidation of democratic institutions, these strukturprobleme are likely to have more serious destabilizing consequences. In this context, a crucial question concerns not simply the link that exists between short-term economic achievements of a nation and stability of its democratic institutions, as the supporters of modernization theory would emphasize (see Lipset 1959; Zapf 1960, 1994, 2002), but also the longterm political legitimacy of the system, as well as the preservation of mass loyalty to the newly-established institutions. This will depend, on the one hand, on the political capacity to manage societal conflicts, while, on the other, to find a response to the new social risks.

Political Dimension

In the political dimension, the main strukturprobleme of post-communist capitalism(s) concern the system-stabilizing capacity of political institutions. This primarily involves the organization and conflict capacity of political institutions to: (i) address internal challenges; (ii) stabilize unstable economies; (iii) manage societal conflicts while finding a response to the emerging new social risks; (iv) ensure mass loyalty and political legitimacy to the system; (v) permit effective interest representation (trade unions' and civic society's organization and conflict capacity); and (vi) deal with the exogenous forces of European Integration and globalization.

Addressing internal challenges in an effective way has probably been the most difficult task that post-communist governments have been called to face. Disintegrative processes initiated with the fall of the Berlin Wall have clearly not disappeared overnight, but have produced long-lasting consequences to the stability of the political systems recently introduced. In fact, even though recent studies (Vanhuyusse 2006) have shown how violent protests have almost been absent in CEE (but not in Russia) during the entire period of transition, the presence and, depending on the periods of crisis, the increasing support for extreme-right or ultranationalist political formations (see Shenfield 2001; Mudde 2005) clearly represents a serious threat to these modern democracies. The 2005 and 2006 annual reports of the European Monitoring Centre on Racism and Xenophobia (EUMC 2005, 2006) highlighted, for instance, not only a worrying lack of systematic data collection concerned with racist crimes in the region, but also, in some cases, that even a general upward trend was taking place. In the Russian Federation, although no accurate information is available, the newspapers continuously report aggressions against minorities or vulnerable groups. In 2005, these corresponded to at least 28 people killed and 366 assaulted (BBC News 2006).

Stabilizing unstable economies would, probably, be the best way to avoid undemocratic drifts. According to the well-known argument of Lipset (1959: 56) "the more well-to-do a nation, the greater the chances it will sustain democracy". Other more recent versions of modernization theory have called attention to the redistributive impact of the nations' economic achievements (see Zapf 1960, 1994, 2002; Vanhanen 1997; Przeworski et al. 2000; Przeworski 2005). For Przeworski (2005), the probability that a democracy survives rises steeply not in terms of GDP growth, as previously emphasized, but rather in terms of per capita income. Despite the possible criticisms concerned with modernization theory (7) in CEE and in the Russian Federation economic instability has been associated with political instability, with left- and right-wing coalitions that have rarely survived the duration of one legislature (Cerami 2006a, 2009) and, even when it happened, such as in the case of Putin's Russia, questions about the democratic quality of the system have been raised (Shevtsova 2003; Politkovskaya 2004; Eicher and Beichelt 2006).

Managing societal conflicts while finding a response to new emerging social risks becomes, in fact, a much more difficult political exercise when governments are facing a moment of severe economic instability. Which were, in this context, the main political and policy strategies put in place by governments in order to deal with the new challenges? In a path-breaking but also highly contestable work, Vanhuyusse (2006) argues, for instance, that some governments in these regions (notably in Hungary and Poland) pursued a divide and pacify strategy. According to the author, the hidden aim of politicians and policy-makers was that of dividing workers by sending them out of the labour market while simultaneously pacifying them by granting access to early-retirement policies and generous unemployment benefits. Unquestionably, while a "pacify strategy" certainly took place in Eastern Europe (but not in Russia where the workers' requests have systematically remained unheard), then it has still to be clarified whether the part concerning the "divide strategy" was an intended, or rather an unintended, outcome of policies that simply aimed at preventing the return to an authoritarian system.

Ensuring mass loyalty and political legitimacy to the system cannot be simplified as a matter of paying social benefits to the most vulnerable groups present at a determined moment in time, but must be understood in terms of a long-term strategy that takes into account the systemic problems of a capitalist society. These strukturprobleme go beyond temporary situations of economic vulnerability and cannot be explained only in terms of economic performance. Can long term mass loyalty and political legitimacy be ensured by simply dividing and pacifying people, while reimbursing them with a low quality of life and extremely limited living standards? Clearly not and this for the simple reason that the construction of political consensus is a highly unstable process which has material, but also normative foundations. It is based not only on minimum income protection, or on the perception that an authoritarian alternative would be more damaging to the individual's own interests (Przeworski 2005), but also on the moral aspirations of citizens. Individuals could decide to renounce some of their interests and benefits in the light of higher moral values, such as the refusal of racist attitudes, solidarity towards more vulnerable groups or other less rational choice oriented elements (see Inglehart 1997.

Permitting effective interest representation could, for example, be another element that would make democracies more attractive to autocracies. Ensuring effective interest representation in transition economies has, however, been an uncompleted and mutilated process. Even though, tripartite consultations have played a crucial role during the entire process of transition by facilitating the introduction and continuation of reforms, mediating different interests and needs (Lado 2003), actors in Eastern Europe, however, have lacked the capacity of being true corporatist actors in both policy formation and implementation. Priority was, in fact, very often given to macro-economic stabilization measures. In this context, state-led corporatism (Schmidt 2006) or, to use Ebbinghaus' typology, a consultation model of social governance (Ebbinghaus 2006) has been the main characteristic of the Central and Eastern European model of post-communist interest representation (Cerami forthcoming). In the Russian Federation, by contrast, due to the presidential (or super-presidential) character of the political system (see Eicher and Beichelt 2006), unilateral state intervention (see Ebbinghaus 2006) seems to have been the main model of social governance. As it happened during communism, tripartite consultations were, in fact, highly subjected to the reasons of the state (or the President).

Effectively dealing with the exogenous forces of European Integration and globalization can also be mentioned as an important factor for the system-stabilizing capacity of political institutions. CEE countries largely benefited from the direct and indirect support of EU institutions, which helped them to find an immediate place in the EU 15 (now EU 27) as well as benefitting them through an increase in trade, which had, in turn, an indirect effect in diminishing the economic vulnerabilities of these small economies in the global arena. In the case of the Russian Federation, however, the impact of EU institutions was clearly more limited due to the obvious different geo-political context. Restructuring the Russian economy was also a much more difficult task due to the size of the country, which multiplied its economic vulnerabilities making policy responses less effective. It comes, then, as no surprise that the democratization process was and still is more difficult to complete in the Russian Federation than in Eastern Europe.

Economic Dimension

In the economic dimension, the main strukturprobleme primarily concern the economic capacity and performance of firms and markets in dealing with endogenous and exogenous pressures. These involve: (i) the macro-economic vulnerabilities of markets; (ii) the companies organization and conflict capacity to deal with the challenges coming from national and international markets; (iii) the development of new institutional complementarities able to produce comparative institutional advantages in the post-communist environment; (iv) the reduction of regional and local disparities (existence of regional and local capitalisms); and (v) corruption and clientelism as self-destructive mechanisms.

Undeniably, the now open economies of Eastern Europe and Russia are characterized by more intense macro-economic vulnerabilities than those usually identified in Western countries (see Scharpf and Schmidt 2000). The collapse of the central planned economy has coincided, in fact, not only with the collapse of the industrial organization, in force for more than forty years, but has exposed these emerging markets to a more severe global competition to which they were, for structural reasons, not ready for. Industrial production and employment rates dramatically decreased, while inflation and poverty rates systematically increased in CEE and with a even higher intensity in the Russian Federation. Even though a stable economic recovery seems to be observable or predicted in the near future (more clearly for Eastern Europe than for the Russian Federation), questions about the long-term economic and social performance of these countries must still be raised (Hanson 2003; Simai 2006). Economic and industrial restructuring is, in fact, an extremely complex and long process of institutional recalibration, which depends not only on the successful actions of policy-makers to deal with internal structural problems, but also on the actions and eventual speculations of foreign investors, whose contributions, more often than not, have worsen the country's own vulnerabilities. In Eastern Europe and in the Russian Federation, foreign speculators have, voluntarily or not, contributed to the increase of inflation rates by buying and selling huge amount of currencies in periods of crisis, as well as, as in the case of big international supermarket chains, altering the equilibrium of the prices of products.

The firms organization and conflict capacity to deal with the challenges coming from national and international markets was clearly more limited in CEE and in the Russian Federation than in Western Europe. Companies in post-communist countries were, in fact, robustly attacked and put under pressure by more competitive Western firms and products, which found it easy to alter the false stability established by the communist planners. Only a few "communist" brands survived the shock of transition, and among the most successful almost none survived takeovers from Western firms. Just to quote a few examples, the East German beer Radeburger, the Vita Cola, the fp6 cigarettes and the Czechoslovak car producer SKODA are now in the hands of foreign investors. The Trabant once the most well known family car of communist citizens, has now completely disappeared from the production and has now become an object for collectors and nostalgica of the communist era. The negative results of the balance of payments speaks clearly in this context. Exception for the Czech Republic and the Russian Federation (8), all Eastern European countries showed in 2005 still negative signs (see Table 1).

A way to reduce these shortcomings could be linked to the development of new institutional complementarities (9) able to produce comparative institutional advantages (see Hall and Soskice 2001) in the post-communist environment. Unfortunately, with the collapse of the central planned economy the set of existing institutional complementarities in force during communism also collapsed. The communist economic system was highly integrated and strong ties existed among all economic sectors. Financial, industrial and labour market institutions were not separate entities, but were fully part of the central planned economy. It comes then as no surprise that once the command economy collapsed, post-communist countries found themselves unprepared in the new open environment. The process of capitalist conversion meant, in fact, a drastic recalibration of the once established institutional structures and associated ties. Rigid financial markets had suddenly to be replaced by more flexible financial markets. Flexible labour markets had also to be introduced practically by dictation. As a result of this difficult process of adaptation, the mobilization of resources and the creation of new businesses, which in return would have sustained the demand, were, even though rapid, not effective at all.

The reduction of regional and local disparities has also become a priority for the economic capacity and performance of firms and markets. The Central and Eastern European and Russian economies are, in fact, still characterized by the existence of very distinct levels of regional and local socio-economic development. The presence of different regional and local capitalisms (see Crouch et al. 2004) seems to apply for the Eastern part of Europe, probably, much more than for the West. Several studies have, in fact, emphasized the presence and the reproduction over time of these disparities (European Commission 2005'; World Bank 2005). In all Eastern European countries and in the Russian Federation, urban areas are not only still much more developed than rural areas, but also have a faster the degree of development in comparison to the catch-up processes of rural areas (EFILWC 2006').

The emergence of corruption and clientelism as self-destructive mechanisms can also be mentioned as a further example of the strukturprobleme that characterize post-communist capitalism(s).

Although the emergence of specific forms of clientelism is not an invention of the West, but rather a heritage of the communist past, where in order to deal with the shortages caused by central planning, "second" and "informal" economies emerged almost everywhere in the region (see, for instance, Szelenyi 1988; Hankiss 1991; Szalai 2005), clientelist relations, that once served to ensure legitimacy for a system unable to provide material support for all citizens and for these functional reasons tolerated by the communist nomenklatura, now contribute to its own disintegration. The Transparency International Corruption Perceptions Index (10) for the year 2006 ranks these countries from the 24th place in the case of Estonia to the 84th in the case of Romania and up to the 12111 in the case of the Russian Federation (Table 2).

Societal Dimension

In the societal dimension, the main strukturprobleme of post-communist capitalism(s) concern the social integration capacity of political and economic institutions. From a societal point of view, the transition from a planned to a market economy could be described in terms of a "social implosion". The major societal changes here have involved three main areas: (i) the social inclusion, (ii) the life chances and (iii) the quality of life of citizens. In terms of social inclusion, post-communist countries have witnessed a rise in poverty, income inequality, social fragmentation, as well as in material, cultural and social deprivation. According to the most recent World Bank estimations (poverty threshold of 2 US dollars a day), even though 40 million people have moved out of poverty as a whole, in the Central and Eastern European and CIS region, more than 60 million still remain poor, while more than 150 million are addressed as being economically vulnerable (World Bank 2005, p. 2). Social exclusion has also drastically increased. The poor are not only more often excluded by the labour market, but also face more difficulties in establishing a decent social life. Material, cultural and social deprivation, certainly not absent even before the fall of the Berlin Wall, have now drastically increased (Simai 2006). Recent studies on intergenerational transmission of poverty conducted in Bulgaria, Estonia, Lithuania, Poland and the Russian Federation (Manning and Tikhonova 2004; Profit 2005a, 2005b) show, for instance, how poverty has now a much more self-perpetuating character than it had during communism, where belonging to, or not, the nomenklatura was the main means of transmission of inequalities.

In terms of life chances, the increase in mortality, drugs and alcohol abuse, infectious diseases, and suicides is one of the main concerns following the dissolution of the Iron Curtain. Statistics provided by the World Health Organization show that mortality rates, which have now diminished in CEE from an average of 1120 per 100 000 inhabitants in 1989 to 971 in 2005, are steadily increasing in the Russian Federation from 1160 in 1989 to 1510 in 2005. Alcohol abuse has also grown as a result of transition. In CEE countries, for example, the pure alcohol consumption (litres per capita) has increased from 8.7 in 1989 to 9.3 in 2005, while in the Russian Federation it has almost doubled (from 5.3 to 8.9). HIV/AIDS has also become a major problem. In Eastern Europe, the number of new HIV infections has increased of twenty times, from an average of 9 in 1989 (without Poland (11)) to 176 in 2005. In the Russian Federation, the number of new HIV infections in 2005 was 131 times higher than in 1989 (from 272 in 1989 to 35739 in 2005) surpassing many third world countries. As correctly emphasized by Zinoviev (quoted in Field and Twigg, 2000, p.5), this can now be described as a form of "self-induced genocide". Last but not least, after the shock of the first years of transition where the number of suicides increased in all countries, the number of suicides and self-inflicted injuries per 100 000 inhabitants in CEE decreased from 23 in 1989 to 19 in 2005, while in the Russian Federation, no sign of improvement (it has increased, in fact, from 27 in 1989 to 30 in 2005) is observable (WHO Health for All Database 2007).

In terms of quality of life, the major political and economic changes have implied an increase in social closure, the deterioration of family relations and traditional family ties, as well as a reduction of social networking capacity, especially for the poorest social strata, with the consequent diminution of possibilities for finding a job. Reports conducted by the European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions (EFILWC) have, in fact, not only constantly emphasized the link existent between poverty and social segregation (in some cases emphasizing also the "self-segregation" character of poverty), but have also highlighted the presence of a North-South as well as of a East-West divide (EFILWC 2004a, 2006b; Manning and Tikhonova 2004). As a consequence of these increasing economic and social gaps, not three (Esping-Andersen 1990) or four (Ferrera 1998), but rather five different "social Europe" seem to characterize the Old Continent in the most disparate areas of the individual's social life. These areas include, for example, income inequality and deprivation (EFILWC 2005a), life satisfaction and happiness (EFILWC 2005b), family, work and social networks (EFILWC 2004b, 2005c), reconciliation of work and private life (EFILWC 2006c), participation in civil society (EFILWC 2006d) as well as the social dimension of housing (European Commission 2005b; EFILWC 2006e).

What Kind of Social Structure is Developing in CEE and Russia?

In the previous section, some of the main strukturprobleme of post-communist capitalism(s) have been highlighted. The following section aims to clarify what kind of social structure is developing in CEE and in the Russian Federation. Dramatic changes clearly occurred in the labour structure, family and household composition, but how dramatic were these changes? The most important impact can, probably, be identified in the emergence of completely new forms of vertical disparities, the positions of individuals in the social class, as well as in new forms of horizontal disparities, increasing poverty and income inequality for households.

Labour Structure

As far as the changes in the labour structure are concerned, these have primarily involved: (i) an increase in the number of unemployed due to the dismissal of workers in numerous state-owned enterprises; (ii) an increase in employment in the private sector (and in self-employment) due to the privatization of the central planned economy, (iii) a drastic decrease of people working in the agricultural and industrial sector only in part covered by an increase in the number of those employed in the service sector; (iv) the formation of a new managerial elite (class), formed, however, in a large part by previous administrators and technocrats (see Szelenyi 1988; Eyal et al. 1998); (v) the emergence of a new middle class, including self-employed people who work in their own enterprises, white-collar workers and intellectuals (Adamski et. al. 2001; Machonin et al. 2001; Speder et al. 2001; Tu?ek 2001; Gyorgy and Robert 2003); and (vi) the dissolution of the once crucial social class of the "skilled manual workers" (Slomczynski and Mach 1997).

As a more in-depth comparison of patterns of employment according to the occupational sector shows, most recently (from 1997 to 2005), that major changes have, first and foremost, involved: 1) the skilled agricultural and fishery workers whose number has doubled in the Russian Federation (+100%), but decreased by one-third in CEE (36%); 2) professionals, whose number has increased by one-third in CEE (+29%) and by one-fifth in the Russian Federation (+22%); and 3) service workers and shop and market sales workers whose number has increased by more than one-third (+48%) in the Russian Federation, and with a lower intensity, by approximately one-tenth (+12%) in CEE. Interestingly, in the Russian Federation, the number of citizens employed as legislators, senior officials and managers have increased by approximately one-forth (+26%) in recent years, while workers in elementary occupations have decreased by approximately one-sixth (-15%) (see Fig. 1). Used with due caution, these results lead to the conclusion that patterns of change in the labour structure have not proceeded with the same speed and intensity in Eastern Europe than in the Russian Federation, even though these two regions share the same communist legacies. CEE countries are, in fact, moving faster towards a labour structure similar to those in more consolidated Western societies (e.g. drastic reduction of farmers), while, in the case of the Russian Federation, the communist transition seems still to be underway, as the growing number of people occupied in the agricultural sector indicates.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

Employment Relations

Changes in the labour structure have also resulted in changes in employment relations and, in particular, in: (a) the dismissal of life-long employment status; (b) the alteration of the relationship between work performance vs. work remuneration; and (c) the establishment of new wage gaps. Fig. 2 shows how the employment ratio (the number of employed as per cent of population aged 15-59) in CEE and in the Russian Federation has dropped from approximately 80% in 1989 to less than 70% in 2004. Despite increasing income differentiation, real wages (the income of an individual after taking into consideration the effects of inflation on purchasing power) have also declined. In 2004, only in CEE were real wages close to the value they had in 1989, while in the Russian Federation they still corresponded to 75% of the value in 1989 (Fig. 3). The "new" phenomenon of the working poor citizens has also dramatically come to the attention of the international community. A forthcoming report of the World Bank emphasizes, for instance, how this category of citizens remains the largest constituents of the poor in both CEE and Russia (World Bank forthcoming). Despite this group of workers being difficult to identify and to quantify, a seminar report prepared for the European Commission suggests that the number in the Eastern region should be substantially higher than the 17% of self-employed people and 6% of those employed present in Western Europe (EFILWC 2004c). Wage gaps (occupational wage gap, generational wage gap, educational wage gap) have also drastically increased. If, on the one hand, this had some positive connotations, since it provided a first response to the excessive income homogeneity in force during communism, where unskilled workers and professionals earned almost the same amount of money (this also resulted in lower economic performance in absence of work incentives), excessive wage differences now exist between the nouveaux riches (those few people who massively benefited from the privatization of the economy) and the rest of the population who continue to suffer for the rise in living expenses. In addition to wage gaps existent between different people employed in different occupational sectors as well as between people of different ages and educational levels, there are also wage differences between men and women (the so-often quoted "gender wage gap") that, once almost nonexistent in the region, have now dramatically increased, with women now facing new forms of gender segregation (Manning and Tikhonova 2004; Pascall and Kwak 2005).

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

Family and Household Composition

With regards to the major changes that are occurring in the family and household composition, these primarily involve an increasing poverty for: (i) single-headed households; (ii) single parents; (iii) single women with children; (iv) households with unemployed, part-time or atypical workers; (v) households with elderly, (vi) households with young people; and (vii) households of the Roma minority. For these groups of people extreme poverty still represents a major and unresolved problem both in CEE and in the Russian Federation (for a brief overview, see World Bank 2005; Cerami 2006a, 2006b, 2009). Extreme poverty, however, is not the only negative outcome, social segregation is also on the increase, with a higher number of family members from these categories now formally excluded by those normal activities that were once available to the society at large (such as access to cultural events) (Manning and Tikhonova 2004; Szalai 2005). Even though these systemic changes are not very different from the ones that are taking place in other post-industrial societies, one should bear in mind that the negative repercussions tend to be multiplied by the more unstable nature of these democracies in transition. As noted by Doma?ski (2005) and Keller (2005), while during communism withdrawal from public life and abstention from active political participation was functional to the survival of the communist system, in the post-communist environment, increasing political apathy represents a serious threat to the stability of democratic institutions since participation in public life and political participation are the foundations of modern democracies.

What Kind of New Social Risks are Emerging? (12)

As a consequence of the strukturprobleme, and changes to the social and political structures, it is important to identify the new social risks faced by CEE countries and the Russian Federation. The literature on new social risks primarily concerned with Western European countries (Esping-Andersen 1999; Esping-Andersen et al. 2002; Taylor-Gooby 2004; Armingeon and Bonoli 2006) identifies as the principal factors for the emergence of new social risks, the de-industrialization and tertiarization of employment, women's entry in the labour market, increasing instability of the family structure, as well as processes linked to the privatization of the welfare state. Can such factors, developed for the West, be applied in toto to Eastern Europe and the Russian Federation as well? Here, one important remark has to be made. Whereas during communism, the main risks that Eastern citizens faced were primarily related to the possibility of not finding the necessary consumables in the shops due the "economy of shortage" (Kornai 1992) or dealing with poor or the bad quality of social services, in the post-communist environment the spectrum of "new" social risks is substantially broader. New social risks include, for example, balancing paid work with family responsibilities, care for elderly parents and lacking skills (or having obsolete skills) in the labour market, as identified for the West, but also having no longer access to a secure job, pension, health care, or minimum income (Cerami 2008).

New Social Risks Types: West vs. East

According to Esping-Andersen's classification (1999, pp. 40-43), three different types of social risks can be identified in Western Europe: class-based risks, life-course risks and intergenerational risks. While class-based risks are primarily concerned with the uneven distribution of risks in the social class, life-course risks tend to involve their uneven distribution during the entire life of the individual. Intergenerational risks, by contrast, are those more directly concerned with intergenerational transmission and inheritance of chances and associated hazards. An example of class-based risks is the possibility of unemployment for those in a poorer social strata due to obsolete training and/or skills, where as life-course risks include increasing poverty for elderly or for younger generations. Finally, intergenerational risks include the possibility that the sons of the unemployed will face higher chances of becoming unemployed themselves. An alternative, but not very dissimilar model proposed by Kitschelt and Rehm (2006) divides new social risks in terms of general existential risks (those concerning the inability to work due to illness and old age), group-specific risks I (those concerning the obsolence of skills due to structural changes), group specific risks II (those concerning the uncertain returns on higher education, e.g. of specific academic fields) and group specific risks III: demographic risks (those concerning the loss of earnings due to demographic reproduction, e.g. raising children).

Regardless the type of classification one decides to adopt, an important question that still has to be clarified regards the fact of whether these new social risks types in the West really correspond to the new social risks types present in the East. Although de-industrialization and tertiarization of employment is occurring both in the West as well as in the East, the social changes associated with the restructuring of the central planned economy, and the fast emergence of a new social structure no longer based on central planning, are a phenomenon only present in Eastern European societies and Russia. Moreover, while the entry of women in the labour market can be addressed as a possible threat to already existing equilibriums present in western labour markets, this certainly cannot be the case for post-communist countries, which were already structurally characterized by higher levels of female employment. Rather, the new challenge that post-communist societies are called to face in this area of social protection seems to be concerned not with a farewell to maternalism, to use Orloff's metaphor (Orloff 2006), but rather with the establishment of new forms of refamilization.

It can, as a consequence, be concluded that in addition to the new social risks types present in Western societies, Eastern societies are also characterized by peculiar "past-dependent" property-related social risks, which find their origin in the restructuring of the central planned economy and in the subsequent changes occurring in the social structure. Here, the term "property" should be understood in the broadest possible sense, including not only material capital (such as the ownership of property assets), but also cultural capital (such as the impossibility of transforming educational skills developed for the communist system to skills that can be used in the post-communist environment), as well as social capital (such as the capacity to develop or to be part of post-communist social networks) (see Cerami 2008.

New Social Risks Groups and Political Preferences

On the basis of the considerations mentioned above, for transition countries, new social risks groups also tend to be larger and more variegated constituencies than those existent in the West. They involve, in fact, a broader spectrum of citizens, which includes the traditional categories present in the West, such as the unemployed, women, young, elderly, handicapped, children, minorities, large families with children, single parents, single women, and working poor (Armingeon and Bonoli 2006; Kitschelt and Rehm 2006), as well as other categories of workers such as all those citizens unable to conduct a reconversion of their material, cultural and social capital (e.g. middle-age employees of ex state-owned enterprises, low level bureaucrats and civil servants, people out of post-communist social networks, etc.).

As it is easy to imagine, these new social risks constituencies will have distinct interests, needs, party preferences and political affiliations. The increasing number of unemployed, pensioners, young and women in part-time or atypical jobs are likely to be an important predictor for the future emergence and political strength of new welfare preferences in the region. It is, in fact, to be expected that in countries where the economic crisis has been stronger there will also be a tendency to develop stronger requests for an active management of the state in protecting against new social risks. Due to the higher number of people involved, these welfare constituencies are also likely to be stronger in Eastern, rather than in Western Europe. The clearest indicator of this trend lies, probably, with the high instability of governments, which characterizes transition countries since the first free parliamentary elections, and the use of economic and social reforms as primary determinants and reasons for governmental change (see Cerami 2006a, esp. pp. 16-29; 2008).

Conclusions

This article has attempted to respond to the three main questions, which were at the core of the investigation. It has been argued that post-communist societies are characterized by more severe strukturprobleme than those usually identified for Western countries. These concern the system-stabilizing capacity of political institutions, the economic capacity and performance of firms and markets, as well as the social integration capacity of political, economic and societal institutions. It has also been argued that these strukturprobleme are associated with faster changes in the social structure, which are, in turn, resulting in the emergence of broader new social risks types and constituencies. Welfare states in these transition economies are, as a consequence of a difficult and still unfinished process of functional, distributive, normative and institutional recalibration, charged with a double burden of responsibilities. They are, on the one hand, called to find an immediate response to more pressing old and new social risks, while, on the other, they are requested to deal with the challenges stemming from more drastic economic, political and societal transformations that has followed their transition towards democracy.

References

Adamski, W., Zaborowski, W. & Nalecz, K. P 2001, The Dynamics of Structural Conflict in the Process of Systemic Change: Poland 1980-2000, Polish national report prepared for the Conference "Structural Changes in Post-Socialist Central Europe and the Actual Challenges of Modernization", Villa Lana, Prague, 11-13 May.

Amable, B. 2003, The Diversity of Modern Capitalism, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Armingeon, K. & Bonoli, G. 2006, The Politics of Postindustrial Welfare States. Adapting Post-War Social Policies to New Social Risks, Routledge, London/New York.

Backhaus, J. G. 2003, Evolutionary Economic Thought. European Contributions and Concepts, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.

BBC News 2006, Russian racism 'out of control', Story from BBC News. Published: 2006/05/04. [Online] Available at: http://news.bbc.co.uk/go/pr/fr//2/hi/europe/4969296.stm

Cerami, A. 2006a, Social Policy in Central and Eastern Europe. The Emergence of a New European Welfare Regime, LIT Verlag, Berlin.

Cerami, A. 2006b, 'Poverty and Social Structure in Russia: An Analysis of the First Decade of Transition' Luxembourg Income Study Working Paper no. 445, Luxembourg Income Study, Luxembourg.

Cerami, A. forthcoming, 'The Politics of Reforms in Bismarckian Welfare Systems: The Cases of Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland and Slovakia', in The Long-Good Bye to Bismarck? The Politics of Reforms in Continental Europe, ed. B. Palier, Amsterdam University Press, Amsterdam.

Cerami, Alfio. 2008. "New Social Risks in Central and Eastern Europe: The Need for a New Empowering Politics of the Welfare State." Czech Sociological Review 44(6):1089-1110.

Cerami, Alfio. 2009. "Welfare State Developments in the Russian Federation: Oil-Led Social Policy and the 'Russian Miracle'." Social Policy & Administration 43(2):105-120.

Cook, Linda, J. 2007. Post-Communist Welfare States. Reform Politics in Russia and Eastern Europe. Ithaca and London: Cornell University Press.

Crawford, B. & Lijphart, A. 1997, 'Old Legacies, New Institutions: Explaining Political and Economic Trajectories in Post-Communist Regimes', in Liberalization and Leninist Legacies, eds. B. Crawford & A. Lijphart, University of California Press, Berkeley, pp. 1-39.

Crouch, C., Le Gales, P, Trigilia, C. & Voelzkow. H. (eds) 2004, Changing Governance of Local Economies: Responses of European Local Production Systems, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Doma?ski, H. 2005, 'The Polish transformation. Structural changes and new tensions', European Journal of Social Theory, vol. 8, no. 4, pp. 453-470.

Ebbinghaus, B. 2006, 'Reforming Bismarckian Corporatism: The Changing Role of Social Partnership in Continental Europe', paper presented at the project conference 'A long good bye to Bismarck? The politics of welfare reforms in Continental Europe', The Minda de Gunzburg Center for European Studies at Harvard University, Cambridge, MA, USA, June 16-18.

Eicher, C. & Beichelt, T. 2006, 'Russland: Stabilisierung einer delegativen Demokratie', in Defekte Demokratie. Band 2: Regionalanalysen, eds. W. Merkel, H-J. Puhle, A. Croissant & P Thiery, VS Verlag fur Sozialwissenschaften, Wiesbaden, pp.297-364.

Ekiert, G. 2003, 'Patterns of Post-Communist Transformation in Central and Eastern Europe', in Capitalism and Democracy in Central and Eastern Europe. Assessing the Legacy of Communist Rule, eds. G. Ekiert & S.E. Hanson, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 89-119.

Esping-Andersen, G. 1990, The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, Polity Press, Cambridge.

Esping-Andersen, G. 1999, The Social Foundations of Postindustrial Economies, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Esping-Andersen, G., Gallie, D., Hemerijck, A. & Myles, J. 2002, Why We Need a New Welfare State, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Ettrich, F 2005, Die andere Moderne. Soziologische Nachrufe auf den Staatssozialismus, Berliner Debatte, Berlin.

European Commission 2005a, Third Progress Report on Cohesion: Towards a New Partnership for Growth, Jobs and Cohesion, European Commission, Brussels.

European Commission 2005b Reconciliation of Work ad Private Life. A Comparative Review of Thirty Countries. European Commission, Brussels.

European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions (EFILWC) 2004a, Quality of Life in Europe. First European Quality of Life Survey 2003, Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg.

European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions (EFILWC) 2004b, Fertility and Family Issues in an Enlarged Europe, Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg.

European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions (EFILWC) 2004c, Working Poor in the European Union. Seminar Report, Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg.

European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions (EFILWC) 2005a, First European Quality of Life Survey: Income Inequality and Deprivation, Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg.

European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions (EFILWC) 2005b, First European Quality of Life Survey: Life Satisfaction, Happiness and Sense of Belonging. Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg.

European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions (EFILWC) 2005c, Families, Work and Social Network, Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg.

European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions (EFILWC) 2006a, First European Quality of Life Survey: Urban-Rural Differences, Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg.

European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions (EFILWC) 2006b, First European Quality of Life Survey: Quality of Life in Bulgaria and Romania. Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg.

European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions (EFILWC) 2006c, Working time and Work-Life Balance in European Countries, Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg.

European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions (EFILWC) 2006d, First European Life of Life Surrey: Participation in Civil Society, Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg.

European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions (EFILWC) 2006e, First European Quality of Life Survey: Social Dimension of Housing, Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg.

European Monitoring Centre on Racism and Xenophobia (EUMC) 2005, Annual Report on the Situation regarding Racism and Xenophobia in the Member States of the European Union, EUMC, Vienna.

European Monitoring Centre on Racism and Xenophobia (EUMC) 2006, Annual Report on the Situation regarding Racism and Xenophobia in the Member States of the European Union, EUMC, Vienna.

Eyal, G., Sz6lenyi, I. & Townsley, E. 1998, Making Capitalism without Capitalists: The New Ruling Elites in Eastern Europe, Verso, London-New York.

Ferrera, M. & Hemerijck, A. 2003, 'Recalibrating Europe's Welfare Regimes', in Governing Work and Welfare in the New Economy: European and American Experiments, eds. J. Zeitlin & D.M. Trubek, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Ferrera, M. 1998, 'The Four 'Social Europes': between Universalism and Selectivity', in The Future of Welfare in Europe: A New Social Contract?, eds. Y. Meny & M. Rhodes, St. Martins, New York, pp. 79-96.

Ferrera, M., Hemerijck, A. & Rhodes, M. 2000, The Future of Social Europe. Recasting Work and Welfare in the New Economy, Celta Editora, Oeiras.

Field, M. G. & Twigg, J.L. 2000, 'Introduction'. in Russia's Torn Safety Nets. Health and Social Welfare during the Transition, eds. M.G. Field & J.L. Twigg, Macmillan, Basingstoke, pp. 1-10.

Gyorgy, L. & Robert, P 2003, 'Middle Classes in the Making in Central and Eastern Europe', in Inequality and Social Structure during Transition, eds. V. Mikhalev, Palgrave Macmillan, New York:, pp. 99-132.

Hall, P. A. & Soskice, D. (eds) 2001, Varieties of Capitalism. The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Hall, P. A. 1997, 'The Role of Interests, Institutions and Ideas in the Comparative Political Economy of the Industrialized Nations', in Comparative Politics. Rationality, Culture, and Structure, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp.174-207.

Hall, P A. 2006, 'Stabilitat and Wandel in den Spielarten des Kapitalismus', in Transformationen des Kapitalismus, eds. J. Beckert, B. Ebbinghaus, A. Hessel & P Manow, Campus, Frankfurt/New York, pp.181-204.

Hankiss, E. 1991, 'The "Second Society": Is There an Alternative Social Model Emerging in Contemporary Hungary?', in Crisis and Reform in Eastern Europe, eds. F. Feh6r & A. Arato, Transaction Publishers, New Brunswick & London, pp. 303-334.

Hanson, P 2003, Can the Russian Economy Keep on Growing?, Centre for Research into Post-Communist Economies, London.

Hemerijck, A. 2006, 'Recalirating Europe's Semi-Sovereign Welfare States', Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin fur Sozialforschung (WZB) Working Paper no. SP 12006-103, WZB, Berlin.

Inglehart, R. 1997, Modernization and Postmodernization, Princeton, University Press Princeton.

International Labour Organization (ILO) 2007, Laborsta, ILO: Geneva, [Online] Available at: http://laborsta.ilo.org/

Keller, J. 2005, 'The Czech Republic. Fifteen years later', European Journal of Social Theory, vol. 8, no. 4, pp. 471-485.

Kitschelt, H. & Rehm, P 2006, 'New Social Risk and Political Preferences', in The Politics of Postindustrial Welfare States. Adapting Post-War Social Policies to New Social Risks, eds. K. Armingeon & G. Bonoli, Routledge, pp 52-82, London/New York.

Kornai, J. 1992, The Socialist System. The Political Economy of Communism, Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey.

Lado, M. 2003, 'Hungary: Why Develop Sectoral Social Dialogue?', in Sectoral Social Dialogue in Future EU Member States: The Weakest Link, eds. Y. Ghellab & D. Vaughan-Whitehead, International Labour Office/European Commission, Budapest, pp. 225-282.

Lipset, S. M. 1959, 'Some social requisites of democracy: economic development and political legitimacy', American Political Science Review, vol. 53, pp. 69-105.

Machonin, P, ?ervenka, J., Gatnar, L., Kucha?, P, Muller, K. & Tu?ek, M. 2001, 'Structural Changes in the Post-Socialist Czech Republic and the Actual Challenges of Modernization', Czech National Report prepared for the Conference "Structural Changes in Post-Socialist Central Europe ad the Actual Challenges of Modernization, Villa Lana, Prague 11-13 May.

Manning, N. & Tikhonova, N. (eds) 2004, Poverty and Social Exclusion in the New Russia, Ashgate, Aldershot.

Manning, Nick and Nataliya Tikhonova eds. 2009. Health and Health Care in the New Russia. Aldershot: Ashgate.

Mudde, C. (ed) 2005, Racist Extremism in Central and Eastern Europe, Routledge, London.

Offe, C. 1973, Strukturprobleme des kapitalistischen Staates. Aufsatze zur politischen Soziologie, Suhrkamp, Frankfurt.

Offe, C. 1986, 'Die Utopie der Null-Option. Modernitat and Modernisierung

als politische Gutekriterien', Soziale Welt, Sonderband 4, pp. 94-117.

Offe, C. 1996, 'Designing Institutions in East European Transitions', in The Theory of Institutional Design, ed. R. Goodin, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 199-226.

Offe, C. 2006, Strukturprobleme des kapitalistischen Staates. Veranderte Neuausgabe, Campus, Frankfurt/New York.

Orloff, A. S. 2006, 'From Maternalism to "Employment for All": State Policies to Promote Women's Employment across the Affluent Democracies', in The State After Statism, ed. J. Levy, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.

Pascall, G. & Kwak, A. 2005, Gender Regimes in Transition in Central and Eastern Europe, Policy Press, Bristol.

Politkovskaya, A. 2004, Putin's Russia. Life in a Falling Democracy, A Metropolitan/Owl Book, New York.

Profit 2005a, European Studies on Equalities and Social Cohesion 1/2005, Lodz University Press, Lodz.

Profit 2005b, European Studies on Equalities and Social Cohesion 2/2005, Lodz University Press. Lodz.

Przeworski, A. 2005, 'Self-enforcing Democracy', in Oxford Handbook of Political Economy, eds. D. Wittman & B. Weingast, Oxford University Press, New York. [Online] Available at: http://www. nyu.ed u/gsas/dept/politics/faculty/przeworski/papers/wittman.pdf

Przeworski, A., Alvarez, M. E., Cheibub, J. A. & Limongi, F. 2000, Democracy and Development: Political Institutions and Well-Being in the World, 1950-1990, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Scharpf Fritz W. and Schmidt, Vivien A. 2000. Welfare and Work in the Open Economy, Volume I: From Vulnerability to Competitiveness, eds. and Vivien A. Schmidt. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Schmidt, V. A. 2006, 'Bringing the State back into the Varieties of Capitalism and Discourse back into the Explanation of Change', paper prepared for presentation for the Annual Meetings of the American Political Science Association, Philadelphia PA, Aug. 31-3 Sept.

Shenfield, S. D. 2001, Russian Fascism: Traditions, Tendencies, Movements, M. E. Sharp, New York.

Shevtsova, L. 2003, Putin's Russia, Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, Washington D.C.

Simai, M. 2006, 'Poverty and inequality in Eastern Europe and the CIS Transition Economies', UN/DESA Working Paper No. 17, UNDESA, New York.

Slomczynski, K. M. & Mach B.W. 1997, 'Dissolution of the socialist working class', in Sisyphus. Social Structure in the Making, Vol. X, Warsaw: IRS Publishers, pp. 93-118.

Speder, Z., Elekes, Z., Harcsa, I. & Robert, P 2001, 'The Outlines of the Transformation in Hungary', Hungarian national report prepared for the Conference "Structural Changes in Post-Socialist Central Europe ad the Actual Challenges of Modernization, Villa Lana, Prague 11-13 May.

Stark, D. & Bruszt, L. 1998, Postsocialist Pathways. Transforming Politics and Property in East Central Europe, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Szalai, E. 2005, Socialism. An Analysis of its Past and Future, CEU Press, Budapest.

Szelenyi, I. 1988, Socialist Entrepeneurs, University of Wisconsin Press, Madison.

Taylor-Gooby, P (ed) 2004, New Risks, New Welfare. The Transformation of the European Welfare State, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Transparency International 2006, Corruption Perceptions Index 2006, Transparency International, Berlin. [Online] Available at: http://www.transparency.org/policy-research/surveysindices/cpi/2006

Tu?ek, M. 2001, 'Transformation of Social Structures in the Czech and Slovak Republics over Past Fifty Years', Czech and Slovak national report pre pared for the Conference "Structural Changes in Post-Socialist Central Europe ad the Actual Challenges of Modernization, Villa Lana, Prague 11-13 May.

Vanhanen, T 1997, Prospects of Democracy: A Study of 172 Countries, Routledge, London/New York.

Vanhuyusse, P 2006, Divide and Pacify: Strategic Social Policies and Political Protests in Post-Communist Democracies, CEU Press, Budapest.

World Bank 2005, Growth, Poverty and Inequality. Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union, World Bank, Washington D.C.

World Bank 2007, Country At a Glance: Bulgaria, Czech Rep., Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Romania, Russian Federation, Slovakia, Slovenia, Washington D.C. World Bank.

Zapf, W. (ed) 1969, Theorien des sozialen Wandels, Kiepenheuer & Witsch, Koln/Berlin.

Zapf, W. 1994, Modernisierung, Wohlfahrtsentwicklung and Transformation. Soziologische Aufsatze 1987 bis 1994, Sigma, Berlin.

Zapf, W. 2002, 'Entwicklung and Sozialstruktur moderner Gesellschaften', in Einfuhrung in Hauptbegriffe der Soziologie. 6. erweiterte and aktualisierte Auflage, eds. H. Korte & B. Schafers, Leske-Budrich, Opladen.

By Alfio Cerami (1)

(1) Alfio Cerami is a research associate at the Centre d'Etudes europeennes of Sciences Po, Paris. He has also been a visiting lecturer at the University of Erfurt (Germany), Sciences Po Paris and the Centre for German and European Studies at the State University of St. Petersburg (Russia).

(2) The countries of Central and Eastern Europe included in this article are Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Romania, Slovakia and Slovenia.

(3) In the course of this research the German word Strukturprobleme, as introduced by Claus Offe (1973, 2006), instead of the English translation "structural problems" will be used. "Structural problems" tend, in fact, to have a different meaning from the original German translation, which more clearly makes reference to "problems of the structure" (or systemic problems).

(4) For the role played by ideas, interests and institutions in the process of institutional change, see Hall (1997).

(5) The concepts of functional, distributive, normative and institutional recalibration have been introduced by Ferrera et al. (2000) and Ferrera and Hemerijck (2003) to describe the changes that contemporary welfare systems are facing. According to the authors, not only an institutional recalibration is taking place in western welfare states, but also a recalibration of the main welfare functions, distributive aspects and basic norms. Recalibration, as a result, is described as an on-going process of domestic lesson-drawing associated to cross-national social learning (see also Hemerijck 2006).

(6) Arguably, the systemic problems of contemporary capitalism(s) can also have a "cultural" dimension, which concerns the specific "Wrtschaftskultur" (economic culture) or "Wrtschaftsstil" (economic style) of a country, as highlighted by the German economist Sombart (for an up- to-date discussion, see Backhaus 2003). Due to the impossibility to conduct a thorough investigation at the micro-level of the citizens' and firms' economic preferences and behaviour, only the key elements of the abovementioned three distinct dimensions will be highlighted in the course of this article.

(7) Opponents of modernization theory have criticized its simplicity in explaining extremely complex and problematic processes of social and institutional change. Modernity has, in fact, too often become synonymous of the West, while the existence of other, different forms of modernity has systematically been neglected or underestimated (Ettrich 2005). In addition, while emphasizing processes of differentiation and rationalization, modernization theory has not paid serious attention to the self-destructive mechanisms that may exist in capitalist societies (Offe 1986).

(8) Please note that the positive results of the Russian balance of payments can be attributed to the massive devaluation of the currency which took place in 1998. The exchange rate changed from 6 to approximately 25 roubles to the US dollar.

(9) In the Variety of Capitalism (VoC) account (see Hall and Soskice 2001), "two institutions can be said to be complementary when the presence of one increases the efficiency of the other" (Amable 2003, p.6), thus, resulting in a comparative institutional advantage. For example, "flexible labour markets may be more efficient when financial markets allow for a rapid mobilization of resources and creation of new businesses that in return sustain labour demand" (ibid.). The key question here is to what extent do changes in one sphere of political economy influence or stimulate change in another sphere (Hall 2006, p. 191)?

(10) Corruption Perceptions Index scores relate to perceptions of the degree of corruption as seen by business people and country analysts, and ranges between 10 (highly clean) and 0 (highly corrupt) (Source: Transparency International web-site. URL: http://www.transparenq.org/).

(11) In Poland the number of new HIV infections was already higher in 1989 than the normal Eastern average. It increased from 517 in 1989 to 652 in 2005.

(12) The reflections present in this part are based on Cerami (2008).
Table 1 Resource Balance
(Exports of Goods and Services Mio. USD)

                      2005

Bulgaria             -4589
Czech Rep.            2546
Estonia               -422
Hungary              -1325
Lamia                -1280
Lithuania            -1705
Poland                -764
Romania              -7927
Russian Federation   103571
Slovakia             -2129
Slovenia              -212

Source: World Bank 2007, Country At a Glance

Table 2 Transparency International Corruption Perceptions Index

Country Rank      Country       2006 CPI Score

                  Estonia            6,7
28                Slovenia           6,4
41                Hungary            5,2
46             Czech Republic        4,8
46               Lithuania           4,8
49                 Latvia            4,7
49                Slovakia           4,7
57                Bulgaria            4
61                 Poland            3,7
84                Romania            3,1
121                Russia            2,5

Corruption Perception Index scares relates to perceptions of the
degree of corruption as seen by business people and country analysts,
and ranges between 10 (highly clean) and 0 (highly corrupt) (Source:
Transparency International web-site. URL:
http://www.transparency.org/).
COPYRIGHT 2009 Romanian Academic Society
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2009 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.

Article Details
Printer friendly Cite/link Email Feedback
Author:Cerami, Alfio
Publication:Romanian Journal of Political Science
Article Type:Report
Geographic Code:4E
Date:Jan 1, 2009
Words:9265
Previous Article:The economic effects of political institutions: are post-communist countries different?
Next Article:The impact of the EU on governance reforms in post-communist Europe: a comparison between first and second-wave candidates.
Topics:

Terms of use | Privacy policy | Copyright © 2021 Farlex, Inc. | Feedback | For webmasters |