Printer Friendly

Research on a Triopoly Dynamic Game with Free Market and Bundling Market in the Chinese Telecom Industry.

1. Introduction

As a form of marketing activity, bundling sales are widespread in operations. Since this kind of behavior may increase sales and profits, many large enterprises even small businesses should consider adopting bundling sales strategy. The form of bundling sell is varied, like bundling pricing, exchanging prizes, presenting the prizes, etc. It is worth noting that the phenomenon of bundling pricing not only occurs between tangible products but may also happen to service products; the telecommunications companies sell smart phone with their own service packages, for instance.

In this paper, we focus on two kinds of bundling products provided by two competitive oligarchies of telecom industry in China and their important partner, Apple Inc. The two telecom companies are China Mobile Communications Corporation (CMCC, for short) and China Union Communication Corporation (CUCC, for short). CMCC constitutes the majority of market share and CUCC, which also has a large market share, firstly collaborates with Apple. Both of them cooperate with Apple by the best-selling iPhone. As a high-end product in the smart phone market, iPhone, compared with other cheaper mobile phones, could be bundled with more communication services provided by the telecom firms.

On the other hand, many customers prefer to choose a package including more services instead of a package including fewer services, because the discount would become deeper under the former situation. As Table 4 shows, an extreme case is that when customers choose CUCC's bundling service package 9, which has numerous services, the price of the iPhone seems to reduce to zero. It is no doubt that this is a stratagem for attracting customers. Since each of the three firms has their own channel for marketing, we also consider three free markets.

Anyhow, the essence of bundling pricing is stimulating the demand according to the discount. Therefore, we concentrate on how the discounts provided by the three firms severally or the different degree of competition between the two telecom firms impacts the stability margin in the dynamic model. In our gaming system, a linear demand function and a constant marginal cost are supposed. In order to conform to the actual situation, we investigated all the data of the service packages for the assignment of the parameters.

2. Literature Review

Based on game theory and rank-dependent utility theory, Tan et al. [1] studied an incomplete information Cournot game in an ambiguous decision environment, and they found players decision-making is affected by their behavioral characteristics and psychological preference. Many researchers have contributed much to the field of dynamic system and dynamic system bifurcation and chaos theory. Li and Chen[2] investigated some new nonlinear equations which have exact explicit parametric representations of breaking loop-solutions. Aziz-Alaoui and Chen [3] researched a new piecewise-linear continuous-time three-dimensional autonomous chaotic system and briefly discussed its complex chaotic dynamics. Zelinka et al. [4] introduced the notion of chaos synthesis and developed a new method for chaotic systems synthesis.

With the consideration of mixed bundling pricing and decision research, Shao and Li [5] studied the bundling and product strategy involving the channel competition, and they found that the retailer preferred the bundling strategy in two channel competitions. Under the consideration of the price bundle offers in the telecommunications industry, Le et al. [6] introduced a Bayesian game model. They investigated the case where operators propose substitutable offers and compete for customers, in order to maximize the operator's revenue. Based on game theory, Ma and Mallik [7] pointed out that, under the manufacturer bundling scenario, the manufacturer would not provide the full product line composed of the basic product, the premium product, and the bundle. Pan and Zhou [8] established a two-layer supply chain with bundling and pricing decisions and found that the manufacturer could earn more if he sells complementary products separately. Mantovani and Vandekerckhove [9] researched the strategies of merging and bundling decisions and showed that bundle strategy could not benefit the consumers because it brings surge in prices in their model. By calculating, R. et al. [10] discussed the optimal bundling and pricing. Chen and Wang [11] researched the pricing policies, subsidy policies, and channel selection policies of different power supply chain structures. In the perspective of the mergers producer, Gaudet and Salant [12] compared the profits of firms under different circumstances. Martin [13] studied the price pooling equilibrium under various conditions that firms produce strategic substitutes or strategic complements. Dilip and John [14] figured out that the price bundling as a usual marketing action could result in the diminution of demand. In the field of decision research, Li and Liu [15] studied the coordination of supply chain between a supplier and a retailer with price and sales effort dependent demand.

With the rise of bifurcation and chaos theory, many scholars have been interested in combining the theories to the game in the domain of economy. Agiza and Elsadany [16] built a nonlinear discrete-time duopoly game assuming the oligarchies have heterogeneous expectations. With the discussion of a 6-dimension dynamical system, Ma and Wu [17] described a triopoly game with two products. They investigated the impacts of the adjustment parameter and the reform of flexible manufacturing could decrease fluctuation risk caused by the instability in multiproduct market. By applying continuation theorem in their research, Wang et al. [18] obtained the sufficient conditions of the existence of positive periodic solutions of a predator-prey system and improved the methods of computation on topological degree. Besides, Yassen and Agiza [19] proposed a delayed bounded rationality model and figured out that the stability region of the model with bounded rationality is reduced when the competitors use different production methods. Bischi et al. [20] showed a dynamic game model and discussed the question of whether the economic hypothesis of the "representative agent" may sometimes impact the results of research. Sarafopoulos [21] conducted the study of a duopoly game which proposes one player has limited rationality and the other uses adaptive expectations. By studying a triopoly price game model, Ma and Wu [22] found the result that the number of time-delay decision makers has no obvious relationship with stability of the system. Based on the Cournot-Bertrand duopoly model, Ma and Pu [23] studied the stability of the system and found only one Nash equilibrium point after calculation. They also showed the bifurcation diagram which could exhibit the behaviors of the system. Elsadany et al. [24] derived a dynamic system with four various firms and indicated that applying a delayed feedback control method can get the stabilization of the chaos. Srivastava and Srivastava [25] confirmed the FACTS devices could regulate the dynamic bifurcations and chaos effectively. Considering a nonlinear cost function, Du et al. [26] investigated the effects of upper and lower limiter on a duopoly game. By establishing a game model which relates to the power market, Tan et al. [27] analyzed the dynamic behaviors in different market parameters and found that the chaos could be controlled to the stable equilibrium point with the time-delayed feedback control method. As to building two different game models, Ma and Guo (2016) investigated the effect of information on the stability. As to building a Cournot model, Ma and Guo [28] investigated a game whose player's decision was based on his estimation. According to the research done by Yue et al. (2016), a point of view that information sharing may not be beneficial to the firms all through is presented. Ma and Ma [29] established a model and found that market competition could lead to bullwhip effect in a supply chain.

In the field of dynamic game, many authors have investigated the products bundled in terms of putting one product A to another product B in a package. However, the reality is often not the ratio of one to one. Therefore, we construct a model in which bundling products accord with ways of one-to-many. Furthermore, our research not only investigates the behavior of bundling pricing but also considers a competition between two monopolies. This initiate consideration enriches the previous studies of bundling pricing and makes the game more realistic.

After the literature review in Section 2, the remaining part of this paper is divided into four sections. Section 3 describes a new-type game model including five subdivided markets, with the consideration of bundling pricing. Besides, we figure out the Nash equilibrium. In Section 4, we do some numerical experiments and analyze the results of the experiments from the perspective of chaos and complexity. Finally, Section 5 is the conclusion of this paper.

3. The Model

3.1. The Assumptions

(a) Assumption. We suppose the market demand is divided into five sections, which is shown in Figure 1. Here, markets A, B, and C represent the market of CMCC's product, the market of CUCC's product, and the market of iPhone separately, and the three markets only have their own products without bundling pricing. Besides, markets AC and BC, respectively, mean the market of bundling product, which is a CMCC's product or a CUCC's product bundled a new iPhone 7. Customers would only buy products from the three free markets, like markets A, B, and C, or buy the bundling product in the bundling market, like market AC and market BC.

(b) Assumption. As shown in Tables 1 and 2, the details of the service packages already fixed by the two telecom companies are presented. We consider the customers only decide which service package to choose, instead of thinking more about the costs incurred by the service out of the package.

(c) Assumption. We assume the period of a service is a month. By the exhibition of Tables 1-4, we define both of the service packages, which are CM 1 and CU1, as a unit of service, which includes 100 minutes' call and 500 M data plan. Thus, the amount of the other service packages is [m.sub.i] or [n.sub.i] ([m.sub.i], [n.sub.i] are constants not less than 1) times as the quantity of the CM 1 or CU 1. We assume the amount of the services offered in market AC (or BC) is m (or n), which is the expectation of [m.sub.i] (or [n.sub.i]). In the same manner, the discounts of the two bundling products are [[mu].sup.i.sub.1] and [[mu].sup.i.sub.2], and their expectations are [[mu].sub.1] and [[mu].sub.2]

(d) Assumption. The price of the two telecom firms refers to the price of a unit of service in one month. We also assume the price of the iPhone 7 equals the real price divided by 24, because of the research period in contrast of the services. All markets use the price list as Tables 1 and 2 show.

(e) Assumption. In order to make the research feasible, we assume that all the discounts of the iPhone 7, which is bundled with one of the service packages in the two bundling markets, are the same since the exact discounts for the telecom firms are trade secret. Because of playing a leading role, we assume the discount of the iPhone 7 is a fixed value, 0.84, according to the price ofthe phone in Table 4, CU 1.

(f) Assumption. Each of the three companies adjusts their price every period under the bounded rationality, in order to maximize their own profits.

3.2. Variable Enactment. A series of specification and variables in this Bertrand game model will be enacted in this section: [p.sub.i](t) (i = 1,2,3) are the definitions for the three products per unit made by the three companies in the period of t. [q.sup.A.sub.1](t), [q.sup.A.sub.2] (t), and [q.sup.A.sub.3](t) are the demands of products provided by CMCC and CUCC and the demands of iPhone 7 in markets A, B, and C severally during the period of t. The linear demand functions are as follows:

[q.sup.A.sub.1] (t) = [a.sub.1] - [b.sub.1][p.sub.1] (t) + [d.sub.1][p.sub.2] (t). (1)

[q.sup.B.sub.2] (t) = [a.sub.2] - [b.sub.2][p.sub.2] (t) + [d.sub.2][p.sub.1] (t). (2)

[q.sup.C.sub.3] (t) = [a.sub.3] - [b.sub.3][p.sub.3] (t) (3)

where [a.sub.i] (i = 1, 2, 3) are the positive parameters of potential demand in markets A, B, and C, on condition that the firms fix their prices to zero. And, then, [b.sub.i] (i = 1, 2, 3) reflect the self-price sensitive coefficients for the three kinds of products. Besides, [d.sub.i] (i = 1, 2, 3) are denoted as the mutual product substitution ratios between the two telecom firms.

And, then, the parameters [q.sup.AC.sub.3](t) and [q.sup.BC.sub.3] (f) mean the demands of iPhone 7 in market AC and in market BC, respectively, during the period of t. The demand functions in bundling markets are given as

[q.sup.AC.sub.3](t) = [a.sub.31] - [b.sub.31][mu][p.sub.3](t) - [b.sub.31][r.sub.31][[mu].sub.1][p.sub.1](t). (4)

[q.sup.BC.sub.3](t) = [a.sub.32] - [b.sub.32][mu][p.sub.3](t) - [b.sub.32][r.sub.32][[mu].sub.2][p.sub.2](t) (5)

where the positive parameters [a.sub.31] (i = 1,2) are the potential demand for the CMCC's bundling product and the CUCC's bundling product from markets AC and BC. And [b.sub.31] (i = 1, 2), which are greater than zero, are the self-price sensitive coefficients for the two bundling products. The parameters [mu], [[mu].sub.1] and [[mu].sub.2] denote the discount given by the three firms. The positive constants [r.sub.3i] (i = 1,2) are the complementarity degree between two products and [b.sub.3i][r.sub.3i] (i = 1, 2) are the cross-price sensitive coefficients.

In bundling markets AC and BC as well, [q.sup.AC.sub.1](t) and [q.sup.BC.sub.2] (t) denote the demand of CMCC's service and CUCC's service in period t. The demand functions are demonstrated as follows:

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (6)

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (7)

where the nonintegral parameters m and n which are not less than 1 are the multiples of the unit of service.

[q.sub.i](t) (i = 1, 2, 3), the aggregate demand functions of three products offered by CMCC, CUCC, and Apple in the period t, are showed as follows:

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (8)

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (9)

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (10)

The total profit functions of the three firms are defined as [[pi].sub.i](t) (i = 1, 2, 3) in the period of t. In addition, we suppose a fixed marginal cost greater than zero for each product. [c.sub.0] is the cost per unit for the service of two telecom firms, and [c.sub.3] is the cost per unit for the iPhone 7.

[[pi].sub.1](t) = [q.sup.A.sub.1](t) [p.sub.1](t) + [q.sup.AC.sub.1](t) [[mu].sub.1][p.sub.1](t) - [c.sub.0][q.sub.1](t). (11)

[[pi].sub.2](t) = [q.sup.B.sub.2](t) [p.sub.2](t) + [q.sup.BC.sub.2](t) [[mu].sub.2][p.sub.2](t) - [c.sub.0][q.sub.2](t). (12)

[[pi].sub.3](t) = [q.sup.C.sub.3](t) [p.sub.3](t) + [[q.sup.AC.sub.3](t) + [q.sup.BC.sub.3](t)] [mu][p.sub.3] (t) - [c.sub.3][q.sub.3] (t). (13)

3.3. The Dynamic Model. On the basis of the bounded rationality in Assumption (f), three firms treat their price as the decision variable. Meanwhile, they adjust their price according to the marginal profit [partial derivative][[pi].sub.i](t)/[partial derivative][p.sub.i] (t) in each period. If the marginal profit is positive in period t, increasing the price in period t + 1 will be profitable. Conversely, if the marginal profit is negative in period t, decreasing the price in period t +1 will be profitable. The nonlinear functions of the marginal profit are as follows:

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (14)

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (15)

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (16)

Hence, the dynamic equations in this model could be given by following form:

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (17)

where we suppose the three companies adjust their price in the speed of [alpha], [beta], and [gamma], which reflect the decision-making of the three enterprises. After taking (14)-(16) into (17), we can get functions as follows:

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (18)

In order to get the positive stable fixed points of the dynamic model, we need the condition of Nash equilibrium state which is [p.sub.i](t + 1) = [p.sub.i](t) (i = 1,2, 3). After calculation, we obtain only one significant solution in which all the prices are positive; that is,

[E.sup.*] = ([p.sup.*.sub.1], [p.sup.*.sub.2], [p.sup.*.sub.3]) (19)

Due to the fact that the length of [p.sup.*.sub.1] (i = 1, 2, 3) is too long to exhibit in this section, we will show the form of them which have taken the fixed parameters in Section 4.

Besides, the Jacobian matrix of dynamic equation (18) is that

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (20)

where

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (21)

The characteristic polynomial of the matrix of (20) is as the function equation (22) shows. Consider

P ([lambda]) = [[lambda].sup.3] + A'[[lambda].sup.2] + B'[lambda] + C' (22)

where A'; B'; and C' will be discussed in Section 4. In addition, we can also figure out the stable region of parameters [alpha], [beta], and [gamma] by the condition of Jury criterion as follows:

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (23)

The stable region is the range where [E.sup.*] will be stable.

4. The Numerical Modeling and Analysis

4.1. The Parameter Setting. It is worth mentioning that we investigate the service package in practice, in order to determine the values of parameters, for instance, m, n, [[mu].sub.1], [[mu].sub.2], and [mu]. As (A.1) and (A.2) show, the tariffs include different service packages which are posted on their official website, respectively. Based on the analysis for each of the first 8 packages, we figure out and suppose that the utility of 1.45 M data is equal to the utility of 1-minute call in CMCC, and the utility of 1.15 M data is equal to the utility of 1-minute call in CUCC. And then we could obtain all the values of the parameters m and n, which are the amount of the service. Each of [p.sup.M.sub.ri] and [p.sup.U.sub.ri] refers to each of their service package prices divided by their price of unit service, separately. We can calculate the parameters [[mu].sup.i.sub.1] and [[mu].sup.i.sub.2], which are equal to [p.sup.M.sub.ri]/m and [p.sup.U.sub.ri]/n, respectively.

Furthermore, compared with the group clients who will be excluded in our research, most individual customers who choose an iPhone 7 in bundling markets would be more likely to buy several specific service packages. The parameters m, [[mu].sub.1], n, and [[mu].sub.2] are assigned the value of 5.5, 0.47, 6.1, and 0.46, respectively. The calculation of the values of them will be presented in Figure 9. In our research, so as to do in-depth study, we assign values for the rest of the parameters which are as follows:

[a.sub.1] = 3.8, [a.sub.2] = 3.8, [a.sub.3] = 4.5, [b.sub.1] = 0.55, [b.sub.2] = 0.55, [b.sub.3] = 0.6, [d.sub.1] = 0.2, [d.sub.2] = 0.2, [c.sub.0] = 0.0006, [c.sub.3] = 0.95, [a.sub.31] = 15, [a.sub.32] = 15, [b.sub.31] = 1.15, [b.sub.32] = 1.15, [r.sub.31] = 05, [r.sub.32] = 05, [mu] = 0.84. (24)

Moreover, [alpha] = 0.16, [beta] = 0.25, and [gamma] = 0.15 when the adjustment parameter is not changed in the experiments.

4.2. The Stable Region. We will do some numerical modeling experiments to investigate how the parameters impact the stable region of Nash equilibrium.

Experiment 1. By the parameters assigned into (14)--(16) and (18)-(22), the Nash equilibrium, the Jacobian matrix, and the characteristic polynomial of the matrix are as follows, respectively.

With valuing all (14); (15); and (16) equal to 0, we can get

0.2[p.sub.2] - 25[p.sub.1] - 2.5[p.sub.3] + 7.68 = 0 0.2[p.sub.1] -2.58[p.sub.2] -2.71[p.sub.3] + 8.01 = 0 9.43 - 0.222[p.sub.2] - 4.45[p.sub.3] - 0.227[p.sub.1] = 0. (25)

Solving (25), we can get

[E.sup.*] = (1.181, 1.272, 1.996). (26)

Equation (25) is the Nash equilibrium. And, then,

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (27)

Equation (26) is the Jacobian matrix. Besides,

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (28)

where

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (29)

Equation (27) is the characteristic polynomial. Moreover, putting (29) into Jury criterion equation (23), we can obtain the system of inequalities which is the stable region. In addition, we acquire the stable region shown in Figure 2(a). As it shows, we set y equal to 0.15 and calculate the stable region by Jury criterion with both a and [beta] changing from zero to one. The figure illustrates that the red region is the stable region, and the deep blue, green, orange, light blue, and pink region refer to the 2, 4, 8, 6, and 5 cycles' regions, severally. The rest of the regions, gray region and white region, are the variable overflow area which means the region of chaos. From this figure, we can know that the prices of the firms will have only one Nash equilibrium solution under the fixed adjusted speed in red region. Also, Figure 2(b) shows the stable region and the other regions using the same colors as [alpha] and [gamma] are changed from 0 to 1, on the condition that [beta] = 025 is fixed. Similarly, with [alpha] assigned the value of 0.16, Figure 2(c) indicates the stable region in the same way as [beta] and [gamma] are changed from 0 to 1.

Experiment 2. In order to investigate the impacts to the stable region on conditions of different degree of competition between the two telecom firms, we did the second experiment and exhibited the result by Figure 3. Obviously, we can find that the stable region decreased when the degree of competition became fierce between the CMCC and CUCC from the picture. Under the circumstance of [gamma] = 0.25, the green, the blue, and the red regions reflect the stability of [d.sub.1] = [d.sub.2] = 0. 1, [d.sub.1] = [d.sub.2] = 0.4, and [d.sub.1] = [d.sub.2] = 0.9, severally.

Experiment 3. By comparing the content plotted in Figure 4, the authors observed that the stable region increased when the degree of the complementarity was enhanced between the telecommunication products to the smart phones. The three regions in Figures 4(a), 4(b), and 4(c) refer to the stabilities under the circumstances of [r.sub.31] = [r.sub.32] = 0.1, [r.sub.31] = [r.sub.32] = 0.5, and [r.sub.31] = [r.sub.32] = 0.9, separately.

In addition, the authors plotted the system's largest Lyapunov exponent (LLE), which was illustrated as the variation of system state, as presented in Figure 5. Note that the system was stable when the LLE was smaller than 0. If the LLE is greater than zero, the system enters into chaos. Without changing others parameters, we obtain the stability scope of [alpha], [beta], and [gamma] in Figures 5(a), 5(b), and 5(c) separately.

4.3. The Impact of Price Adjustment Parameters. For the sake of investigating the impact of price adjustment parameters, we plot the bifurcation diagrams by changing the adjustment parameters, [alpha], [beta], and [gamma] in Figures 6(a), 6(b), and 6(c). For the three subfigures, the blue line marked [p.sub.1] reflects one unit price of service package offered by CMCC, and the red line refers to one unit price of service package offered by CUCC, and finally the green line represents the price of the iPhone 7. After a period of stability, the system begins bifurcation as the parameter [alpha] goes. The system goes into period four and then period eight, and afterwards it enters into chaos. When the chaos appears, it would be hard for the managers to make decision.

4.4. The Impact of Bundling Amount. The impact of parameter m will be investigated in this section according to Figure 7. We can see that both [p.sub.1] and [p.sub.2] decrease with the value of m increases in Figures 7(a) and 7(b). Conversely, [p.sub.3] grows up with the increasing of m in Figure 7(c).

4.5. The Chaos Attractor. Figure 8 shows the chaos attractor. In Figure 8(a), the horizontal axis and vertical axis refer to the prices of the service packages of CMCC and CUCC, and then we set a equal to 0.93. Similarly, in Figure 8(b), the horizontal axis and vertical axis refer to the prices of the service package of CMCC and iPhone 7, and then the authors set a equal to 0.95. The chaos attractor means a little variation in the initial condition could cause a diverse and unpredictable output. Hence, the firms may suffer enormous risks with competition in the market of chaos. The fluctuations in prices, which are the decision variables made by firms every periods, exert the negative effects.

5. Conclusion

In this research, we build a dynamic triopoly model which includes two competitive telecom firms in China and their correlative corporation, which produces the complementary product. Both their free markets and the markets of bundling pricing products are considered in order to make the model more realistic. We do some numerical experiments to research the Nash equilibrium solution, the stable regions, bifurcation of prices, the LLE, and the chaos attractor. The valuable conclusions by our research are as follows: Firstly, we can find that the stable region will decrease when the degree of the competition becomes fierce between the two competitive firms. Secondly, the stable region will increase if the degree of the complementarity enhances between the telecommunication products to the smart phones. Thirdly, moderately increasing the amount of bundling services not only can lead to the decrease of the prices of two telecom firms when the system is stable but also can increase the price of iPhone 7. Hence, for CMCC or CUCC, moderately decreasing their services in packages without the variation of other conditions can increase their service prices. And, finally, we give the regions of chaos, which should be avoided, from the perspective of economics.

Our research enriches the existing papers about bundling pricing. This research has managerial significance of not only the three firms discussed, but also the enterprises simulated to the three firms. The result of this model may help the managers adjust their decision-making with their experiences. Certainly, there are more studies that should be done in the future, such as considering the firm, which produces the complements, which has different discounts for the two firms, or the innovation of the products in the background of electronic products, etc.

https://doi.org/ 10.1155/2018/5720392

Appendix

See Tables 1, 2, 3, and 4 and Figure 9.

Based on our research, as shown in Figure 9, we investigate P(Mi), which means the probability of the customers choosing the service package of CM i (i = 1, 2, ..., 8), and also investigate the P(Ui), which refers to the probability of the customers choosing the service package of CU i (i = 1, 2, ..., 9). So, the expectations of m, [[mu].sub.1], n, and [[mu].sub.2] are as follows:

m = [8.summation over (i=1)][m.sub.i]P (Mi) (A.1)

[[mu].sub.1] = [8.summation over (i=1)][[mu].sup.i.sub.1]P (Mi) (A.2)

n = [9.summation over (i=1)][n.sub.i]P (Ui) (A.3)

[[mu].sub.2] = [9.summation over (i=1)][[mu].sup.i.sub.2]P (Ui) (A.4)

Data Availability

The data used to support the findings of this study are available from the corresponding author upon request.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare that they have no conflicts of interest. Acknowledgments

The research was supported by the National Natural Science

Foundation of China (no. 71571131).

References

[1] C. Tan, Z. Liu, D. D. Wu, and X. Chen, "Cournot game with incomplete information based on rank-dependent utility theory under a fuzzy environment," International Journal of Production Research, pp. 1-17, 2016.

[2] J. Li and G. Chen, "On nonlinear wave equations with breaking loop-solutions," International Journal of Bifurcation and Chaos, vol. 20, no. 2, pp. 519-537, 2010.

[3] M. A. Aziz-Alaoui and G. Chen, "Asymptotic analysis of a new piecewise-linear chaotic system," International Journal of Bifurcation and Chaos, vol. 12, no. 1, pp. 147-157,2002.

[4] I. Zelinka, G. Chen, and S. Celikovsky, "Chaos synthesis by means of evolutionary algorithms," International Journal of Bifurcation and Chaos, vol. 18, no. 4, pp. 911-942, 2008.

[5] L. Shao and S. Li, "Bundling and product strategy in channel competition," International Transactions in Operational Research, 2017.

[6] H. Le Cadre, M. Bouhtou, and B. Tuffin, "Consumers' preference modelingto price bundle offers in the telecommunications industry: A game with competition among operators," NETNOMICS: Economic Research and Electronic Networking, vol. 10, no. 2, pp. 171-208, 2009.

[7] M. Ma and S. Mallik, "Bundling of Vertically Differentiated Products in a Supply Chain*," Decision Sciences, vol. 48, no. 4, pp. 625-656, 2017.

[8] L. Pan and S. Zhou, "Optimal bundling and pricing decisions for complementary products in a two-layer supply chain," Journal of Systems Science and Systems Engineering, vol. 26, no. 6, pp. 732-752, 2017.

[9] A. Mantovani and J. Vandekerckhove, "The strategic interplay between bundling and merging in complementary markets," Managerial and Decision Economics, vol. 37, no. 1, pp. 19-36, 2016.

[10] R. Venkatesh and W. Kamakura, "Optimal Bundling and Pricing under a Monopoly: Contrasting Complements and Substitutes from Independently Valued Products," Journal of Business, vol. 76, no. 2, pp. 211-231, 2003.

[11] X. Chen and X. Wang, "Free or bundled: channel selection decisions under different power structures," Omega , vol. 53, pp. 11-20, 2015.

[12] G. Gaudet and S. W. Salant, "Mergers of producers of perfect complements competing in price," Economics Letters, vol. 39, no. 3, pp. 359-364, 1992.

[13] S. Martin, "Oligopoly limit pricing: Strategic substitutes, strategic complements," International Journal of Industrial Organization, vol. 13, no. 1, pp. 41-65, 1995.

[14] D. Soman and J. T. Gourville, "Transaction decoupling: How price bundling affects the decision to consume," Journal of Marketing Research, vol. 38, no. 1, pp. 30-44, 2001.

[15] Q. Li and Z. Liu, "Supply chain coordination via a two-part tariff contract with price and sales effort dependent demand," Decision Science Letters, vol. 4, no. 1, pp. 27-34, 2015.

[16] H. N. Agiza and A. A. Elsadany, "Chaotic dynamics in nonlinear duopoly game with heterogeneous players," Applied Mathematics and Computation, vol. 149, no. 3, pp. 843-860, 2004.

[17] J. Ma and F. Wu, "The application and complexity analysis about a high-dimension discrete dynamical system based on heterogeneous triopoly game with multi-product," Nonlinear Dynamics, vol. 77, no. 3, pp. 781-792, 2014.

[18] H. Wang, Z. Zhang, and W. Zhou, "Existence of positive periodic solutions for a nonautonomous generalized predator-prey system with time delay in two-patch environment," Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society, vol. 2012,12 pages, 2012.

[19] M. T. Yassen and H. N. Agiza, "Analysis of a duopoly game with delayed bounded rationality," Applied Mathematics and Computation, vol. 138, no. 2-3, pp. 387-402, 2003.

[20] G.-I. Bischi, M. Gallegati, and A. Naimzada, "Symmetry-breaking bifurcations and representative firm in dynamic duopoly games," Annals of Operations Research, vol. 89, pp. 253-272, 1999.

[21] G. Sarafopoulos, "Chaotic effect of linear marginal cost in nonlinear duopoly game with heterogeneous players," Journal of Engineering Science and Technology Review, vol. 8, no. 1, pp. 19-24, 2015.

[22] J. Ma and K. Wu, "Complex system and influence of delayed decision on the stability of a triopoly price game model," Nonlinear Dynamics, vol. 73, no. 3, pp. 1741-1751, 2013.

[23] J. Ma and X. Pu, "The research on Cournot[??]CBertrand duopoly model with heterogeneous goods and its complex characteristics," Nonlinear Dynamics, vol. 72, no. 4, pp. 895-903, 2013.

[24] H. N. Agiza, E. M. Elabbasy, and A. A. Elsadany, "Complex dynamics and chaos control of heterogeneous quadropoly game," Applied Mathematics and Computation, vol. 219, no. 24, pp. 11110-11118, 2013.

[25] K. N. Srivastava, "Elimination of dynamic bifurcation and chaos in power systems using facts devices," IEEE Transactions on Circuits and Systems I: Fundamental Theory and Applications, vol. 45, no. 1, pp. 72-78, 1998.

[26] J. Du, Y. Fan, Z. Sheng, and Y. Hou, "Dynamics analysis and chaos control of a duopoly game with heterogeneous players and output limiter," Economic Modelling, vol. 33, pp. 507-516, 2013.

[27] T. Tan, H. Yang, and X. Deng, "Time-delayed feedback chaos control of dynamic cournot game of power market based on heterogeneous strategies," in Proceedings of the Transmission and Distribution Exposition Conference: 2008 IEEE PES Powering Toward the Future, PIMS 2008, usa, April 2008.

[28] J. Ma and Z. Guo, "The parameter basin and complex of dynamic game with estimation and two-stage consideration," Applied Mathematics and Computation, vol. 248, pp. 131-142, 2014.

[29] J. Ma and X. Ma, "Measure of the bullwhip effect considering the market competition between two retailers," International Journal of Production Research, vol. 55, no. 2, pp. 313-326, 2017.

Junhai Ma (iD), Tiantong Xu (iD), and Wandong Lou (iD)

College of Management and Economics, Tianjin University, No. 92, WeiJin Road,

NanKai District Tianjin 300072, China

Correspondence should be addressed to Junhai Ma; mjhtju@aliyun.com and Tiantong Xu; ttxu201608@126.com

Received 30 March 2018; Revised 31 May 2018; Accepted 3 June 2018; Published 11 July 2018

Academic Editor: Jorge E. Macias-Diaz

Caption: Figure 1: The structure of the model.

Caption: Figure 2: (a) The stability with [alpha] and [beta] is changed and [gamma] = 0.15. (b) The stability with [alpha] and [gamma] is changed and [beta] = 0.25. (c) The stability with [beta] and [gamma] is changed and [alpha] = 0.16.

Caption: Figure 3: The stability of three values of [d.sub.1], [d.sub.2], with [alpha], and [beta] is changed, and [gamma] = 0.25.

Caption: Figure 4: (a) The stability with [alpha] and [beta] is changed, and [gamma] = 0.25; [r.sub.31] = [r.sub.32] = 0.1. (b) The stability with [alpha] and [beta] is changed, and [gamma] = 0.25 and [r.sub.31] = [r.sub.32] = 0.5. (c) The stability with [alpha] and [beta] is changed, and [gamma] = 0.25 and [r.sub.31] = [r.sub.32] = 0.9.

Caption: Figure 5: (a) The LLE as [alpha] changes. (b) The LLE as [beta] changes. (c) The LLE as [gamma] changes.

Caption: Figure 6: (a) Bifurcations of [p.sub.i] as [alpha] goes when [beta] = 0.25 and [gamma] = 0.15, (b) bifurcations of [p.sub.i] as [beta] goes when [alpha] = 0.16 and [gamma] = 0.15, and (c) bifurcations of [p.sub.i] as [gamma] goes when [alpha] = 0.16 and [beta] = 0.25.

Caption: Figure 7: (a) Bifurcations of [p.sub.1] when m = 5.5 and 6.2, (b) bifurcations of [p.sub.2] when m = 5.5 and 6.2, and (c) bifurcations of [p.sub.3] when m = 5.5 and 6.2.

Caption: Figure 8: (a) The chaos attractor when [alpha] is 0.93, [beta] = 0.25, and [gamma] is 0.15. (b) The chaos attractor when [alpha] is 0.95, [beta] = 0.25, and [gamma] is 0.15.
Table 1: The price list of CMCC.

service package    call plan (min)   data plan (M)

CM 1                     100              500
CM 2                     220              700
CM 3                     500             1000
CM 4                     500             2000
CM 5                    1000             2000
CM 6                    1000             3000
CM 7                    2000             3000
CM 8                    4000             6000

service package    price of service package (RMB)    [m.sub.i]

CM 1                             58                    1.00
CM 2                             88                    1.58
CM 3                             138                   2.67
CM 4                             158                   4.22
CM 5                             238                   5.35
CM 6                             268                   6.90
CM 7                             338                   9.15
CM 8                             588                   18.29

Table 2: The price list of CUCC.

service package    call plan (min)   data plan (M)

CM 1                     100              500
CM 2                     200              800
CM 3                     300             1000
CM 4                     500             1000
CM 5                     500             2000
CM 6                     500             3000
CM 7                    1000             4000
CM 8                    2000             6000
CM 9                    3000             11000

service package    price of service package (RMB)    [n.sub.i]

CM 1                             56                    1.00
CM 2                             76                    1.67
CM 3                             106                   2.19
CM 4                             136                   2.56
CM 5                             166                   4.19
CM 6                             196                   5.81
CM 7                             296                   8.37
CM 8                             396                   13.5
CM 9                             596                   23.5

Table 3: Details of the service package offered by CMCC.

service package            CM 1   CM 2    CM 3    CM 4    CM 5

service price in the        58     88      138     158     238
  actual situation
price of the phone in      5388   5388    5388    5388    5388
  bundling product
price of the phone         4540   4540    4540    4540    4540
  after mathematic
  transaction
gift calls                 348     528     828     948    1428
service price after        78.8   101.3   138.8   153.8   213.8
  mathematic transaction
total cost                 6432   6972    7872    8232    9672
price ratio                1.0    1.29    1.76    1.95    2.71
  ([p.sup.M.sub.ri])
[m.sub.i]                  1.0     1.6     2.7     4.2     5.3
[[mu].sup.i.sub.1]         1.00   0.81    0.66    0.46    0.51

service package            CM 6    CM 7    CM 8

service price in the        268     338     588
  actual situation
price of the phone in      5388    5388    5388
  bundling product
price of the phone         4540    4540    4540
  after mathematic
  transaction
gift calls                 1608    2028    3528
service price after        236.3   288.8   476.3
  mathematic transaction
total cost                 10212   11472   15972
price ratio                3.00    3.66    6.04
  ([p.sup.M.sub.ri])
[m.sub.i]                   6.9     9.1    18.3
[[mu].sup.i.sub.1]         0.43    0.40    0.33

Table 4: Details of the service package offered by CUCC.

service package            CU 1    CU 2   CU 3   CU 4    CU 5    CU 6

service price in the        56     76    106     136     166     196
  actual situation
price of the phone in      4549   4359   4069   3779    3489    3199
  bundling product
price of the phone after   4549   4549   4549   4549    4549    4549
  mathematic transaction
gift calls                  0      0      0       0       0       0

service price after         56    68.1   86.0   103.9   121.8   139.8
  mathematic transaction
total cost                 5893   6183   6613   7043    7473    7903
price ratio                1.00   1.22   1.54   1.86    2.18    2.50
  ([p.sup.U.sub.ri])
[n.sub.i]                  1.0    1.7    2.2     2.6     4.2     5.8
[[mu].sup.1.sub.2]         1.00   0.73   0.70   0.72    0.52    0.43

service package            CU 7    CU 8    CU 9

service price in the        296     396     596
  actual situation
price of the phone in      2239    1279      0
  bundling product
price of the phone after   4549    4549    4549
  mathematic transaction
gift calls                   0       0       0

service price after        199.8   259.8   406.5
  mathematic transaction
total cost                 9343    10783   14304
price ratio                3.57    4.64    7.26
  ([p.sup.U.sub.ri])
[n.sub.i]                   8.4    13.5    15.1
[[mu].sup.1.sub.2]         0.43    0.34    0.48

Figure 9: (a) The probability distribution of [m.sub.i].
(b) The probability distribution of [n.sub.i].

(a)

          probability distribution

P(M1)            0.3%
P(M2)            0.7%
P(M3)            2.4%
P(M4)           30.9%
P(M5)           31.0%
P(M6)           32.7%
P(M7)            1.8%
P(M8)            0.2%

(b)

          probability distribution

P(U1)            0.1%
P(U2)            0.2%
P(U3)            0.5%
P(U4)            1.2%
P(U5)           32.2%
P(U6)           32.7%
P(U7)           31.6%
P(U8)            1.5%
P(U9)            0.0%

Note: Table made from bar graph.
COPYRIGHT 2018 Hindawi Limited
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2018 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.

Article Details
Printer friendly Cite/link Email Feedback
Title Annotation:Research Article
Author:Ma, Junhai; Xu, Tiantong; Lou, Wandong
Publication:Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society
Geographic Code:9CHIN
Date:Jan 1, 2018
Words:6820
Previous Article:Implementation Flexibility of Multiperiod Rail Line Design with Consideration of Uncertainties in Population Distribution.
Next Article:Control of Chaos in a Single Machine Infinite Bus Power System Using the Discrete Sliding Mode Control Technique.
Topics:

Terms of use | Privacy policy | Copyright © 2019 Farlex, Inc. | Feedback | For webmasters