Printer Friendly

Pay differentials: the case of Japan.

In review of industrial relations research conducted during the 1970's, James G. Scoville writes that, in both Japan and the United States, size-of-firm wage differentials are explained by differences in employees' human capital. However, two recent studies suggest that human capital differences do not completely explain the differential in this country. Using data for 1979, Wesley Mellow found that wages in firms of 1,000 more workers were 8 percent greater than those in firms with fewer than 25 workers when a number of factors, including education and experience, were held constant. Martin E. Personick and Carl B. Barsky, who studied pay at various experience and responisbility levels of professional, technical, and clerical occupations, reported size-of-firm differentials for all but 1 of 25 job levels. Typically, these were only for the largest corporations (more than 10,000 employees), where differentials were 10 to 15 percent for professionals and 20 percent for clerical and technical occupations over pay in firms with 500 or fewer employees.

If elements of human capital do not completely explain size-of-firm differentials in the United States, is Japan a similar case? This article explores that issue, and suggests an answer based on data from the Chingin Kozo Kihon Tokei Chosa [Wage Structure Survey]. The employment decision in Japan

The model employment relationship in Japan is that of Shushin Koyo ]lifetime employment]. Under this system, workers are initially employed upon graduation from school. Once a worker is hired, the firm goes to great lengths to provide continuous employment until the individual retires, sometime between the ages of 50 and 60. In return for the understood employer commitment to long tenure, the employee is expected to devote himself fully to the firm and to allow management considerable flexibility as to the type and geographical location of work assignments.

Remuneration consists of a basic wage, various allowances, a semiannual bonus, and a number of fringe benefits. The basic wage depends upon the employee's education, age, and job abilities. It is increased annually based upon decisions made in collective bargaining. The annual increase consists of two parts, one of which recognizes an additional year of service to the firm, new job abilities, and merit, and another that is a general increase in the base wage.

Given the employment opportunities and wage patterns faced by the graduating student, what pecuniary variable should be used in making the employment decision? Clearly, it is some subjective assessment of the present value of future earnings with the various firms. Such a present value calculation would incorporate growth of the firm relative to the economy, the pattern of wages associated with long tenure, the pattern of wages if tenure is short because of voluntary mobility or the firm's economic difficulties, and so forth. For the observer trying to approximate such individual calculations, the most desirable data would be those on wage and bonuses by worker age, education, and length of service, and, for the question at hand, the size of the employing firm. Fortunately, these data are available in the annual Wage Structure Survey. It is thus possible to account for the principal elements of huamn capital that economists believe are important for wage determination, and to differentiate these among three size-of-firm categories. (Of course, the individual graduate also considers other, unquantifiable factors, such as his preference for risk, the prestige of the firm, and subjective probabilities of advancement, in making the final decision.) Differentials by size of firm

Table 1 presents monthly wage and wage-plus-bonus relationships by size of firm and by workers' age and educational attainment for Japanese men who have been continuously employed by the same firm. (In 1980, about one-fourth of the regular private-sector labor force were employed by firms of 1,000 workers or more, and another one-fourth were in firms with 100 to 999 employees.) According to the table, compensation is generally less in the smaller companies, regardless of worker age or education. Monthly wages are about the same in the two smaller size classes until workers are in their forties, when those in the mediumsize firms begin to receive more. When bonus payments are included as compensation, the differences between the largest and smallest firms become more dramatic. In general, the higher teh level of education, the larger is the wage gap by size of firm.

To more fully illuminate these relationships, table 2 presents compensation relatives by industry for broad age categories of high school and college educated men. Ata underlying the estimates relate to individuals whose tenure suggests theat they have been continuously employed by the same firm since graduation. Thus, only a few of all possible matched age-tenure pairs are shown, but these represent core groups in the economy. Two distributions are presented, one for monthly wages and one for monthly wages plus one-twelfth of annual bonus payments. Again, the inclusion of bonuses tends to increase the income differences among the three size-of-firm classes, and the benefits of working for the larger firms increase with age and tenure.

The pay relatives suggest little in the way of systematic variation by industry, although those for transportation and communication tend to be quite high in samller firms while those in finance and insurance are comparatively low. The indices of each industry's differentials were ranked and compared to rankings by union penetration and proportion of total employment in large firms by industry. Neither comparison indicated any systematic relationship with size-of-firm differentials.

Except for occupations that require substantial training--airline pilots, construction crafts, and so forth--occupational distinctions are weakly, if at all, correlated with wages in Japan. Hence, while table 3 shows significant occupational wage differentials by size of firm, these results may be less meaningful than estimates based on other variables.

The data in table 2 do suggest capital investment with its own rewards. Yet the greater opportunity to achieve long tenure which characterizes employment in large firms should also be seen as an additional benefit to such employment, unless the individual worker has a positive taste for risk. New graduates are quite aware that their prospects for long tenure with a large firm are more promising than with a smaller firm. For example, in 1981, 19.4 percent of all college educated men age 45 to 49 were employed in firms with 1,000 workers or more had worked 20 or more years for their current employer. The figure for those in firms with 100 to 999 workers was 54.5 percent, and for firms with 10 to 99 workers, it was 31.7 percent. Earnings data for 50-to 54-year-old high school educated men suggest that workers do not have to pay a compensation premium for the greater probability of long tenure: Among those with 30 or more years of tenure, wages plus bonuses in large firms are 17 percent higher than in middle-size firms and 31 percent higher than in small firms, while the comparable figures for similary aged workers at all levels of tenure are 25 percent and 40 percent.

Employment opportunities for women, especially at high-level jobs and with the major employers, are markedly different from those for men, although there have been changes toward equality during the postwar years. In particular, men's wages increas more with age: In 1981, the 50- to 54-year-old high school educated male with 1 to 2 years of firm tenure had a monthly wage that was 56 percent higher than that of a similary educated 18- to 19-year-old. Among women, the worker age 50 to 54 received only 17 percent more than her younger counterpart. Yet, firm-specific tenure appears to be relatively more valuable for older women than for older men. This is probably because women with brief tenure are likely to have been in the labor market for only a short time, which is not typically the case for men. Yet, when the compensation of high school educated workers with at least 30 years' tenure was compared by size of firm, the patterns for men and women were quite similar. Women's wages plus bonus in firms with 1,000 workers or more were 18 percent higher than in firms with 100 to 999 workers, and 26 percent higher than in small firms. Again, there is no compensation premium paid by workers for the probability of long tenure in larger firms: At ages 50 to 54 for all levels of tenure, wages plus bonus for women in the largest firms were 36 percent higher than in middle-size firms and 44 percent higher than in the smallest firms. The puzzle

It seems clear in Japan, as in the United States, that the standard human capital variables of education and experience do not completely explain, if ever they did, size-of-firm differentials. In addition, it is evident that the Japanese differential is much larger after age 40 or when bonus income is included. Any explanation, therefore, must be consistent with the age pattern demonstrated and the concentration of the differential in the bonus portion of compensaton.

It is possible that a more exhaustive test of work characteristics would reduce the size of the differential. We know, for example, that the most able students enroll in the very best schools, from which the larger, more successful corporations seek employees. Yet it seems unlikely that such difficult-to measure characteristics of employees could explain wage differentials of the magnitude shown in the tables.

Widening differential with age. Some recent studies of compensation by age include variables for implicit contracts, experience, risk, incentives, and so forth, that may explain the Japanese pattern. One approach incorporating a variety of these concepts was presented in a 1982 article by Milton Harris and Beng Holmstrom.

According to the authors, there are four possible reasons why compensation increases with age: a) firms learn about individual abilities and are better able to match workers to jobs; b) workers begin to pay employers lower implicit premiums to guarantee their ability to do acceptable work; c) employees learn productivity-enhancing skills; and d) pay levels are a particulary important means to motivate employees in a world of lifetime employment security. The first two of these, while consistent with a general widening of the wage differentials over time, do not imply a rapid shift after the age of 40. The second two appear to be more relevant.

In the larger firms, there is more physical capital per worker, which could yield greater productivity, and thus justify higher wages. It also is probable that the interaction of higher quality employees with similar employees and with higher levels of physical capital generates greater increases in human capital in the larger firms. The development of productivity enhancing skills with additional tenure may well be an important element in the ability of large firms to pay high wages. Indeed, in the context of a technology-specific skills model, Hong Tan has argued that such gains over a working life are key determinants of Japanese wage patterns. A somewhat similar argument was made by Kazuo Koike, who hypothesized that the more developed system of internal training in large firms provides a greater range of technologically related positions than is true in smaller firms, which in turn contributes to wage differentials by size of firm. However, even if enhanced skills are an important factor, there remains the problem of timing. Why should so much of the differential be concentrated in the years after age 40?

The last element, motivational allowances, may best explain the time pattern. As is well known by the organizers of games of chance, large prizes and prizes that are ever in the future seem to have disproportionate power to motivate participants when compared to their discounted value. Many of the new employees in major Japanese firms wll not be there to collect their "prize" at older ages, but the promise of greater compensation is a constant motivating factor. Thus, the firm saves money compared to paying an annual motivational allowance to each employee. In a sense, the firm also has received an interest-free loan from the employee, who has tacitly agreed to defer a portion of compensation to later worklife. In a rapidly growing economy, such an arrangement is highly advantageous to the firm, but even in less dynamic times an interest-free loan has value.

Japanese institutions. There are two institutional factors unique to Japan which also have significantly affected the time pattern of the differential and its size. The concept of a living wage based upon family needs has long been important in Japan. It is rooted in the nation's history, but has become more prominent since World War, I, and particularly since the economic difficulties of the post-World War II years. The concept provides that wages should increase over a worker's life to accommodate marriage, the birth of children, the high costs of private college, and savings for early retirement from the primary employer. The latter two factors would suggest significant wage increases after the age of 40.

The second institutional consideration is that the nature of the large corporation in postwar Japan is quite different than in prewar years. Formerly, corporations were uniquely capitalistic, owned and controlled by wealthy individuals. However, share ownership in postwar Japan has tended to be diluted into the hands of other firms and banks. There is a high proportion of capital in the form loans and internally generated funds, and an almost complete absence of outside directors. These changes, in conjunction with Japanese historical patterns and moral visions, have persuaded many scholars that today's large firms are essentially collectives of employees who hire high risk-high gain capital from shareholders and low risk-fixed gain capital from banks. If the assumption that the Japanese corporation is a collective of employees which hires capital rather than a collective of owners of capital which hires workers (including senior managers) is valid, it is hardly surprising that economic rents are shared among the members of the collective--the employees.

The extensive use of bonus payments as the mechanism to pay out significant portions of the higher income received by employees in large firms is more complicated to explain. The payment of a semiannual bonus is a very old Japanese practice which was intended to provide employees with sufficient funds to meet the extra needs associated with certain cultural and religious practices. The bonus also served to provide a measure of equity and motivation in the form of profit sharing. However, with the democratization of employment in the postwar years, a significant bonus, which to an extent had been reserved for white-collar and management employees, was extended to all workers.

While extensively used by all Japanese employers, the bonus tends to be relatively larger in the larger firms, while smaller firms compete for labor on the basis of regular monthly wages. The emphasis small firms give to wages as opposed to bonuses seems to be attributable to two factors: First, the firm wants to provide a monthly wage to cover the necessities of life, and second, a somewhat less rosy employment future gives any "promised" bonus made by a smaller employer less value than an equivalent promise by a large employer. Consequently, one would expect that smaller firms would first meet competitive levels in monthly wages, and only later meet those of the bonus. Patterns over time

There is no simple measure of the degree of wage difference by size of firm because the wage ratios between alternative matched pairs do not all move together. To describe movements over time, I chose to examine wages for 35- to 39-year-old male high school graduates with 15 to 19 years of tenure who worked as production workers in manufacturing (table 4). In addition, data on wage dispersion are provided for selected years (table 5). According to table 4, size-of-firm differentials that were quite wide in 1955 closed somewhat, reaching near equality in 1964. The 1960's were a period of generally tightening differentials as the labor market became much more competitive, and the productivity levels of small firms approached those of large firms. After 1967, the differential gradually widened until a second period of near equality occurred during the oil-shock years 1973-74. This second narrowing was undoubtedly related to inflation, for employment growth in manufacturing had leveled off, turning negative by 1972.

The estimates in table 4, which have been standardized for industry, general type of work, age sex, education, and firm tenure, suggest that size-of-firm wage differentials have remained relatively constant since 1975. However, the figures in table 5, which exclude bonuses and include data for workers at all levels of education and years of firm tenure, show a continuing narrowing of the dispersion of wages within the three size classes. Both tables imply that there has been a greater narrowing of differences between firms of 10 to 99 employees and those with 100 to 999 employees than between the latter and firms of 1,000 and more employees. A comparison with the United States

Recent estimates of size-of-firm differentials in the United States, cited earlier, permit some limited comparison. Wesley Mellow's estimate of an 8-percent pay advantage in firms of 1,000 workers of more over firms with fewer than 25 employees appears relatively modest compared to most of the differentials for Japanese men shown in tables 1 and 2. In the United States, as in Japan, the large-firm differential was greater when specific firm tenure was not considered, and the differential existed across all major industries, although the U.S. diffierential appeared to be greater in manufacturing than in nomanufacturing.

Personick and Barsky's study of professional, technical, and clerical occupations revealed as typical 10- to 15-percent differentials for professionals and a 20-percent gap for clerical and technical occupations between firms of 10,000 or more employees and those with 500 or fewer employees. Although these estimates are for for quite different firm-size classes, they do approximate the differentials reported in table 1 for younger Japanese high school and college graduaes, but they are smaller than those for older college educated males. Interestingly, the U.S. size-firm differential seemed to be larger for workers with less than a college education. Also, the U.S. differentials were larger for entry-level positions than for higher levels of experience. Again, this is the opposite of the Japanese case, in which differentials widen at older ages. These differences between the two countries are consistent with a situation in which large firms pay above-market prices in oder to pick and choose among applicants whose employment potential has not yet been established, but in which one economy embraces the norm of continuous tenure from graduation while the other anticpates considerable interfirm mobility at younger ages.
COPYRIGHT 1984 U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 1984 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.

Article Details
Printer friendly Cite/link Email Feedback
Author:Evans, Robert, Jr.
Publication:Monthly Labor Review
Date:Oct 1, 1984
Words:3100
Previous Article:Occupational mobility and job tenure in 1983.
Next Article:A comparison of youth unemployment in Australia and the United States.
Topics:


Related Articles
Measuring wage premiums for job risks.
Understanding recent changes in the wage structure.
Working under different rules.
Relative price determination in the medium run: the influence of wages, productivity, and international prices.
Interindustry wage differentials: patterns and possible sources.
Pay premiums up the ranks.
Japan's economy.
Prediction of flow patterns in the polyurethane foaming process by numerical simulation considering foam expansion.

Terms of use | Copyright © 2016 Farlex, Inc. | Feedback | For webmasters