Printer Friendly

Land and Society in Edwardian Britain.

By Brian Short (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1997. xvii plus 378pp. $69.95).

When historians look back on the activities of the pre-1914 Liberal Government in Great Britain, they are most likely to emphasize the manner in which David Lloyd George (as Chancellor of the Exchequer) and his colleagues laid the foundations of the twentieth-century "welfare state" in the form of old age pensions, government-operated labor exchanges, a system of contributory national health insurance, a pioneering program of unemployment insurance, and the earliest example of the progressive income tax. What they have often tended to forget is that the "Wizard of Wales" first entered Parliament as the professed enemy of "landlordism," and that it was his hope to use his office to redistribute the national wealth by taxing wealthy landlords in order "to wage implacable warfare against poverty and squalidness." (p. 19) But was Britain's wealth in the early twentieth-century primarily to be found among the great landlords rather than among industrialists and financiers? Or was Oscar Wilde's Lady Bracknell correct in alerting us to the paradox that "land gives one position, but prevents one from keeping it up"?

Whatever the case, the turn-of-the century radical land reform movement did secure two significant clauses in the "People's Budget" of 1909. One of them was a tax on "unearned increment" in land (e.g. land that gained in value solely because it chanced to be located on the outskirts of an expanding city); the other was a tax on "unimproved" land, property held not to produce crops or as a building site but solely for purposes of speculation. After a storm of controversy and a new general election, that budget was enacted into law, and the clauses were put into effect. Critics continued to berate the policy as a prelude to land nationalization, however, and as an attack on all private property. Ten years later, after adverse legal judgments and four years of world war, and while Lloyd George was presiding as prime minister over a predominantly Conservative cabinet, the two taxes were quietly repealed. The cost of administration had proved four times as high as the amounts collected. These were the very years (1918-1922), to be sure, when a quarter of all land in England changed hands and when, in the new Irish Free State, the old Anglo-Irish landowning class was bought out altogether. In England the prime catalyst to such sales was an inheritance tax as high as forty per cent. (Curiously enough, what may have been the most rapid transfer of land in England since the Norman Conquest goes unmentioned in this book.)

Because they were soon repealed, the land taxes in the 1909 Budget are remembered as no more than a curious interlude, but as we are reminded by Dr. Brian Short, Reader in Human Geography at the University of Sussex, the requisite prelude to those two taxes was the great Valuation of 1910-1914, the first (and only) attempt since the Domesday Book of 1086 (which involved one-twentieth as many people) to describe and to assess the value of every single piece of landed property in England and Wales, urban and rural, from the largest estate to the smallest cottage. Some 10,700,000 forms were sent out; 9,600,000 were returned. A majority of the individual returns were afterwards destroyed, but the process led to the amassing of 95,000 Field Books with forty million pieces of information, "the most comprehensive set of property records ever compiled in the United Kingdom" (p. 125) and "the largest data bank in British history." (p. 342) Having first explained how that great valuation came to be, Dr. Short devotes the remainder of the volume to an assessment of both the importance and the limitations of this vast (and thus far little used) body of information. He goes on to provide a series of well-documented case studies (supplemented by tables, photographs, and cartoons) based in whole or in part on the survey. They illuminate property ownership in an urban slum, a middle-class seaside community, and in rural communities devoted to agriculture, to slate-quarrying, and to declining industry.

As Short makes clear soon enough, the records are difficult to use because the parish as defined in the survey often differed from the parish as defined politically or ecclesiastically. Also, whereas the Field Books ended up in the Public Record Office at Kew, the Valuation Books that help explicate the organization of the Field Books ended up (assuming they were not destroyed) in county record offices scattered across the country, while the applicable ordnance survey maps are not necessarily available in conjunction with either. In England, unlike Ireland, only after one hundred years will researchers be allowed to consult the original Enumerators' Books of the Census of 1911 thereby at last "allowing physical structures to be correlated with household information to give a wealth of social and domestic detail unmatched in British historical studies." (p. 112)

Even as matters stand, the aspiring researcher can learn, or confirm, a great many details about Edwardian society, especially about property ownership and tenancy. There were significant urban, suburban, rural, and regional variations, but owner-occupiers constituted no more than one family head in seven. Most of the rest rented the houses in which they lived by the year, by the quarter, or, most commonly, by the month or the week. In many small communities, the median number of rooms per house was four or five, but sanitation was confined to an outdoor earth closet (often shared with another household), water was accessible only from wells, and electrification had scarcely begun. A rural village butcher shop might be immediately connected with "a slaughterhouse as well as a goosebox, pigsty, cart-shed and stables." (p. 193)

After chapters focusing on the distinct and less comprehensive manner in which the valuation survey impinged on Ireland and on Scotland, Short reminds the reader in his conclusion of the various contexts in which his subject may be placed: Commons versus Lords; Radical Liberal versus Patrician Tory; Land versus Stockjobber Capital; the growing power of the bureaucratic state. He reminds aspiring researchers also that neither geographers nor historians can subsist on theory and methodology alone; they must still fix their attention on hard nuggets of historical evidence. With these, as this book makes clear, the social historian of Edwardian Britain is plentifully supplied.

University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign
COPYRIGHT 1999 Journal of Social History
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 1999, Gale Group. All rights reserved. Gale Group is a Thomson Corporation Company.

Article Details
Printer friendly Cite/link Email Feedback
Title Annotation:Review
Author:Arnstein, Walter L.
Publication:Journal of Social History
Article Type:Book Review
Geographic Code:4EUUK
Date:Sep 22, 1999
Words:1067
Previous Article:The Aristocracy in Twelfth-Century Leon and Castile.
Next Article:A Coffee Frontier: Land, Society, and Politics in Duaca, Venezuela, 1830-1936.
Topics:


Related Articles
"Shattered Nerves:" Doctors, Patients, and Depression in Victorian England.
New Perspectives on the Late Victorian Economy: Essays in Quantitative Economic History, 1860-1914.
Poverty and Compassion: The Moral Imagination of the Late Victorians.
Images of Youth: Age, Class, and the Male Youth Problem, 1880-1920.
The Aristocracy in Europe: 1815-1914.
Capitalism in Context: Essays on Economic Development and Cultural Change in Honor of R. M. Hartwell.

Terms of use | Copyright © 2017 Farlex, Inc. | Feedback | For webmasters