Flujos comerciales entre PECOs y paises de la UE: ?cuales son las perspectivas futuras?
Trade Flows Among CEEC and EU Countries: What are the Future Perspectives?1. INTRODUCTION (1)
The process of enlargement has originated a vast literature trying to quantify its economic effects, particularly upon trade relations. Many analyses report changes in terms of volume, composition and nature of trade between EU countries and the CEEC during the process of transition. The enlargement to the East represents an opportunity for trade expansion for both the EU and the CEEC, and in effect trade relations between the EU and the CEEC grew considerably during the last decade.
In what concerns the impacts on trade, one key aspect is whether trade potential between the EU and the CEEC has already been exhausted. Studies on the effects of enlargement on trade have presented contradictory results about the overall trade effects of gradual integration of CEEC into international markets. While some papers conclude that actual EU-CEEC trade is either close to potential level or above potential (see for example Festoc, 1997 or Nielson 2000) others claim that it is still possible for trade relations to expand (for example Buch and Paizolo, 2000 or Jakab et al, 2001). Other authors have focused on the determinants of trade relations and on the evolution of the specialization patterns.
In this paper we analyse the characteristics of EU-CEEC trade relations during the transition period. In addition, we investigate the determinants of bilateral trade flows and analyse the potential trade between the EU countries and the CEEC (2), giving particular attention to the relations among the CEEC. The evolution of intra-CEEC trade relations has not been receiving enough attention in the literature. The strong dynamics of intra-CEEC trade is not only a result of geographic proximity, but mostly a consequence of industrial location strategies from western companies, which led to the development of cross flows within sectors between countries of the same sub-region. On the one hand, multinationals firms try to take full advantage of geographic and economic proximity and establish strategic positions in these emergent markets. On the other hand, they intend to collect the benefits of economies of scale and technology spill over effects by organizing more competitive clusters which cross the CEEC national borders. In the context of the recent enlargement, one might expect the intra-regional flows among CEEC to increase faster than EU-CEEC trade.
One other feature that has not been receiving enough attention in the empirical literature is the sectoral dimension of trade. In this paper, an attempt is done to ascertain industry differences in the evolution of trade. In fact, most studies consider homogeneity of goods produced using the same proportions of factors. However, lately it has been recognised that the heterogeneity of factor endowments and technological contents draws from different determinants. Therefore, we adopt a classification of industries based on the factors that are considered decisive for the competitiveness of each sector (3) and try to identify the determinants of these trade flows.
The paper is organised as follows. Section 2 reports the global and sectoral trends of trade between CEEC and EU, giving particular attention to the relations among the CEEC. Section 3, examines the model specification and the results on the determinants for both total bilateral trade and sectoral trade flows. Section 4, gives a brief overview of earlier empirical studies on potential trade and investigates the potential trade flows among these countries. In section 5 some conclusions are presented.
2. THE DYNAMICS OF EU-CEEC TRADE
2.1. GLOBAL TRENDS DURING THE TRANSITION PERIOD
The collapse of centrally planned economic regimes in the CEEC, and the subsequent process of economic liberalisation, brought along important transformations in economic terms and of course in external trade. The European Agreements were an additional determinant for these countries' reforms. More than 10 years have passed since the process of transition started and it is possible to identify some major tendencies in the CEEC-EU trade (4). The CEEC' openness to world markets was rapid and generalised, with the degree of trade openness (5) evolving from 56% in 1993 to around 80% in 2001 in global terms. In some countries like Estonia, Slovakia, Czech Republic and Hungary, the degree of trade openness already exceeded 100%, which clearly underlines the importance of external trade in new EU members. One other issue that is worth mention is the fact that the CEEC display high and increasing structural trade deficits (around 7,5% of GDP in 2001). In the Baltic countries and in Bulgaria the trade deficit was above 10% of GDP in 2001, resulting from the deterioration occurred during the last decade.
In this period, there was a progressive orientation of the CEEC trade relations to the EU, which coincided with the decline in the relationships with old members of COMECON. In effect, in 2001, the weight of EU in the CEEC total exports was about 66% (while in 1993 was of 54%), which was close from the EU-15 average. Though, in spite of the intensification of the trade among the old and new members of the EU, the commercial unbalances have subsisted and the trade relationships with EU have been responsible for about 50% of those countries deficit in 2001. Yet, EU members' contribution for this deficit is not equal for all the countries. In fact, Italy, France and Finland have been responsible for around 74% of EU surplus, whereas Germany, Austria (6), Denmark, Greece and Portugal present a deficit in their trade with the CEEC.
In spite of the expansion of the EU-CEEC trade relations, the weight of CEEC in the EU total trade continues to be small in global terms, contributing 5% and 4,3% to the exports and imports, respectively, in 2001 (see Table 1). However, the situation was not similar for distinct countries, with Austria, Greece and Germany displaying the highest values while in the EU peripheral countries, as Portugal and Spain, the weight of CEEC did not exceed 1% of total trade. Trade intensity (7) is quite different across countries as well, being Hungary, the Czech Republic and Poland, amongst the new members, and Germany, Austria and Finland, on the part of the older EU members, those which are clearly more involved in reciprocal trade. The intensity of bilateral trade is also heterogeneous, being the relationships more intense in the following cases: Austria and Germany with Hungary, the Czech Republic, Slovenia and Slovakia; Greece with Bulgaria and Romania; and Finland and Sweden with the Baltic countries. On the contrary, the level of trade is low between the CEEC and the Iberian countries and Ireland, in spite of an increase in recent years. So, the intensity of bilateral trade is higher for neighbouring countries, which are therefore closer in economic, cultural and historical terms (see table 2 and 3).
Reflecting these asymmetries, new members that share a common border with the former EU members are responsible for 82% of CEEC trade with the EU (8), while the Balkan and Baltic countries present figures of around 10,5% and 7,5%, respectively (Caetano et al., 2004). In what concerns EU member states, trade is also concentrated in frontier countries. Germany, Austria and Italy are responsible for more than 64% of trade with the CEEC. Portugal, Ireland and Greece, on the other hand, generated only 2,5% of such.
As a consequence of the geographical reorientation of the CEEC trade after the collapse of the economic regimes, the weight of the intra-CEEC trade in the total trade of these countries has registered a slight reduction, from 14,7% to 13,8% between 1993 and 2001. However, in terms of trade dynamics among these countries, there was a sharp decline of 35,8% in the relative intensity of the trade in this period, which was particularly noticeable between 1993 and 1997. After 1997, it was in the former-Czechoslovakia, Estonia and Hungary that the decline in the intensity of trade with other CEEC has occurred (see table 4).
It has to be referred also that trade was particularly intense in the several sub-regions (CEEC-5, Baltic and Balkan countries- see table 5), which reinforces the conviction that geographical proximity has been a decisive factor of trade intensity and it will probably continue to be a central issue after the recent enlargement.
2.2. TRADE PATTERNS BY FACTOR PRODUCTION
CEEC' economic liberalisation altered the relative costs of production factors, causing adjustments in productive structures and trade patterns which reflected the pattern of comparative advantages in the countries (9).
The traditional approach of the comparative advantages pattern relies on the proposition that goods may be classified according to the factor intensities and proportions used in the productive process. Hence we can adopt this approach to explain the structure of trade among CEEC and EU. We employed in this work a classification of sectors according to the factors that are determinant for the competitiveness of each sector (following Boillot et al., 2003). Accordingly, we have considered five groups of goods: Natural Resources, Labour, Scale and Capital, Specialised Suppliers (differentiated goods) and R&D.
In 1993, CEEC exports to the EU were fundamentally based on natural resources and labour intensive sectors, reaching about 64% of total exports to the European Union (see Table 6). Profound changes have occurred in the sectoral pattern of comparative advantages in these countries and in 2001 those sectors represented only about 42%. On the other hand, exports of capital and R&D intensive goods displayed a significant increase, from 13% to 28% of total exports to EU. The differentiated goods exhibited also a positive evolution.
However, there is strong heterogeneity among the countries, with the most significant progress occurring in the CEEC-5, where the weight of scale and capital-intensive industries in total exports was higher than in any other Eastern EU-members. These countries show a sharp decline in the labour intensive industries, as well as strong growth in capital-intensive sectors and differentiated goods. On the other hand, the CEEC imports present a similar evolution (Caetano et al., 2004), suggesting a growing demand for sophisticated goods, from sectors technologically more advanced and that use more qualified labour.
Therefore, the pattern of Revealed Comparative advantages (10) of the CEEC-EU trade had undergone significant transformations. Nevertheless, in 2001 the CEEC comparative advantages were still in sectors intensive in natural resources and unskilled labour (see Table 7). In opposition, the comparative advantage of EU countries arises in sectors intensive in R&D, capital and specialised suppliers.
It is also important to refer that along the years there was an increase in the degree of heterogeneity for the several countries and it is possible to identify different tendencies in the specialization pattern.
First, those countries with higher level of GDP per capita (CEEC-5) became progressively less dependent on sectors intensive in natural resources and unskilled labour (11). Second, the comparative advantage of the Baltic countries is still based on natural resources, with the industries of wood and its byproducts, and oil refinery highly contributing to this situation. These countries major disadvantages are in sectors intensive in capital, R&D and specialised suppliers. Within the Baltic countries, Estonia presents a different evolution since it reveals advantages on differentiated goods (12), built on a few electrical and home-appliances components (13). Finally, the Balkan countries are in an intermediate situation, as advantages are based on sectors more intensive in labour and natural resources, while comparative disadvantages emerge on industries producing differentiated products or intensive in capital and R&D. Moreover, there were not significant changes in the trade structure in the Balkan countries.
Meanwhile, the composition and intensity of factors in the trade relations among the CEEC have not changed much (see table 8). While in the CEEC exports to the EU, differentiated goods and labour intensive products are more important, in the trade among CEEC products intensive in capital and scale and in natural resources are of greater magnitude. Nevertheless, in the CEEC exports to the EU there was a high dynamics of the differentiated goods and of the products intensive in R&D and capital and scale, while sectors intensive in natural resources and labour have lost weight in the CEEC exports.
Analysing the level of technology employed during the production process allows us also to conclude that there are different tendencies among the countries. In the intra-CEEC trade, flows based on low technology continue to prevail (they are about 51% of the total intra-CEEC trade, whereas represent only 30% of the CEEC exports to the EU). Trade in goods of high technology represents only 16% of the intra-CEEC trade against 31% in the exports to the EU. The dynamics of the exports to EU countries in the period 1993-2001, was the main responsible for this situation as the average products and high technology products have increased more than 9pp.
In short, in the transition period there were several different trends in the CEEC trade partners. On the one hand, in the exports to the EU there was a rapid growth, in particular in R&D intensive sectors and in differentiated goods. On the other hand, trade relations among CEEC were relatively sluggish, not only in terms of trade intensity but also on the sectoral pattern of trade among these countries. Also, there was an increasing divergence of trade patterns among CEEC which suggests different factor endowments, as well as distinct dynamics of integration into the international networks of production.
3. EMPIRICAL METHODOLOGY AND RESULTS
In order to study bilateral trade relations between the EU countries and the CEEC, and to predict the trade adjustments associated with the removal of trade barriers, we estimate a gravity model for the period 1993- 2001, considering data not only on EU countries but also on the CEEC. Besides analysing total bilateral exports we also take a sectoral approach. This later aspect is important as the countries and sectors involved in enlargement display different characteristics and therefore they are expected to have different determinants. As a consequence, one of the aims of this paper is to analyse the relative importance of the determinants of trade for several sectors, which has not been common in the literature. One of the exceptions is Marques and Metcalf (2005), which have concluded that in fact the determinants of trade differ across sectors. Yet, these authors use a different sectoral classification and a different methodology.
In this paper, following previous studies (like Egger, 2000 or Fontagne et al., 1999), bilateral trade flows are modelled as a function of the sum of GDP of both countries (GDT), the degree of similarity between the two countries (SIM) and the economic distance between the two countries (ED) (14). We also included the geographic distance between the countries, the existence of a common border and two other dummies: EU (indicating whether both countries belong to the European Union or not) and CEFTA (15) (that equals one if the two trading partners were members of CEFTA).
There are several specifications that may be adopted to estimate a gravity model. In this study we try to use appropriated econometric procedures to obtain more accurate results. More specifically a panel data approach is employed in order to take into account unobserved country heterogeneity. We consider a panel data model with both time and individual specific effects. Also we consider a general specification using trading pair-specific or bilateral common effects as it was proposed by Fontagne et al. (1999), Egger and Pfaffermayer (2003) and Cheng and Wall (2005), which claimed that it is the best specification. Furthermore, it is argued that this general model, considering common bilateral effects, gives better in sample predictions. This type of model assumes that there are systematic differences across pairs of countries captured by country-pair constants. These effects control for all time invariant factors that are specific to each of the trading pairs. Mores specifically the model is:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [[delta].sub.ij] represents the unobservable country pair effect, [[gamma].sub.t] the unobservable time effect and [[epsilon].sub.ijt] is the remainder stochastic disturbance term. The time dummies were included to capture the effects of any variables affecting bilateral exports that vary over time and that are constant across country pairs. Note also that in this specification we have allowed the country-pair effects ([[delta].sub.ij]) to differ according to the direction of the trade, which means that is <5,y is not equal to [[delta].sub.ij]. Both dependent variable and explanatory variables included in the model are in logarithms to the exception of dummies.
If [[delta].sub.ij] and [[gamma].sub.t] are assumed to be fixed parameters to be estimated and the explanatory variables are considered independent of [[epsilon].sub.ijt] then we have a fixed effects error component model. On the other hand, if [[delta].sub.ij] and [[gamma].sub.ij]t are treated as random variables then we have a random effects model. In the random effects model, the explanatory variables are assumed to be independent of [[delta].sub.ij] [[epsilon].sub.ijt] and [[delta].sub.t]. The Hausman test can be used to compare the Within estimator from the fixed-effects model and the random effects GLS estimator, testing the null hypothesis of no correlation between the individual and time effects and the regressors.
In the present case, the tests performed did reject the existence of no correlation. Hence, in order to obtain consistent estimators, we estimate a fixed effects model employing the Within estimator. In addition, in all regressions we calculate heteroscedastic consistent standard errors in order to correct for heteroscedasticity problems.
However, the inclusion of country-pair fixed effects does not allow the estimation of the coefficients of the variables which are time-invariant like geographic distance, the existence of frontier, EU or CEFTA. Therefore, we use a two-step procedure proposed by Arellano and Bover (1990) in order to obtain these coefficients. This procedure consists on a regression of the country-pair effects obtained in the within estimation on the time-invariant explanatory variables. The results for the several sectors and for the total exports can be seen in Table 9. In general the results are in accordance with those usually obtained in the empirical literature on trade. The estimates support the idea that the size of the economy has a statistically positive influence on bilateral trade relations. On the other hand, countries' economic distance, measuring the relative factor endowments, seems to have a negative impact on bilateral trade flows, which is according to new trade theories. Moreover, according to Linder (1961) the higher the economic distance between countries the bigger the differences in their demand structures. Therefore, trade between countries with similar demand structures is more of intra-industry trade nature and less of inter-industry nature. The results seem to be according to this hypothesis and we may conclude that, for total trade and for most sectors, intra-industry trade dominates. It is reasonable to expect that the Linder effect does not occur in all the sectors. In fact, the impact of economic distance seems to be not significant for natural resources and labour intensive sectors. This is not surprising as in natural resources and labour intensive sectors the nature of trade in mainly of inter-industry type, as predicted by HOS models.
In addition, the results provide evidence in support of economic geography models which state the importance of geography (Krugman, 1991). Indeed, distance, as well as frontier, exert a significant influence on the determination of trade flows, both total and sectoral. In fact, the results suggest that R&D sectors seem to be more negatively affected by distance than any others. Also, the existence of common border although with a positive effect in all cases, displays a smaller magnitude in the case of R&D. The distance coefficient is always negative. If distance can be seen as a proxy of all possible trade costs sources we may conclude that an improvement in physical infrastructures will certainly have a positive effect on decreasing the market access gap between the centre and the periphery of Europe.
In this model economic integration is proxied by two dummies, EU and CEFTA. The EU dummy shows the expected result, with the EU integration increasing trade flows among countries on total trade and in all sectors considered. On the other hand, CEFTA is in general positive and significant, with the exceptions of the natural resources and the R&D sectors. For R&D sectors the CEFTA variable is significant and negative, implying that this economic agreement did not benefited trade in the sectors intensive in technology. Also, the EU integration seems to be special important for trade in R&D sectors.
4. ANALYSIS OF POTENTIAL TRADE FLOWS
Different theoretical and empirical approaches have analysed the levels of "potential trade" between the CEEC and the EU. Gravity models have been the most widely adopted in assessing the impact of the enlargement on trade potential. The results of these studies have been contradictory, as some (like Hamilton and Winter, 1992; Baldwin, 1994; Buch and Piazolo, 2000; Jakab et al, 2001 or Ferragina et al., 2005), concluded that there is still scope for growth on the EU-CEEC trade and others refer that trade potential is either close to the potential level or even above potential (for example Gros and Gonciarz, 1996; Festoc ,1997 and Nilsson, 2000).
The distinct results are mainly due to two reasons. On the one hand, it must be noted that the integration process of the CEEC into international markets was very rapid and, as a result, there was a fast expansion of trade flows between the EU and the CEEC. On the other hand, there are some issues concerning data and econometric procedures employed in empirical analyses that raise doubts on the estimates of some of these studies.
First, many studies use cross-section instead of panel data. Previous papers (Breuss and Egger, 1999; Egger, 2000 and Matyas, 1997, 1998) conclude that the use of cross-section data turns the potential trade estimates unbiased. Second, when applying panel data methods there is the issue of deciding whether to apply a random effects or a fixed effects model. Usually the fixed effects model reveals itself as the best and, as a consequence, other aspects have to be considered. Many studies use only data on Western countries, performing out of sample predictions to forecast the results for the CEEC, whereas the fixed effects refer only to the countries in the sample. Most of the recent studies, like Nilsson (2000), Buch and Piazolo (2000) or Jakab et al. (2001), although applying different methodologies, base their estimates on data on both the CEEC and the Western countries. The other issue to take into account is the option between the use of country specific fixed effects and country-pair specific effects. The latter specification is more general and it has been referred recently as the most appropriated (16), but it has not been usually applied on the analysis of trade relations between the CEEC and the EU countries.
Few studies have analysed trade among CEEC in particular after the collapse of the central planned regimes. Fidrmuc and Fidrmuc (2003) and Boillot et al. (2003) are exceptions. The first found a decline on bilateral trade intensity among these countries following the collapse of COMECON. Also, they concluded that trade between EU15 and the CEEC were close to the potential level at the end of the 1990s. The latter have confirmed that trade among the CEEC is particularly intense inside the several sub-regions like the Baltic and Balkan areas.
In line with previous literature, the estimates from the gravity model presented before were used to analyse whether the potential trade between the EU and the CEEC is above or below the actual level. We computed in-sample predictions of trade between the EU and the CEEC countries in 1993, 1997 and 2001 and compare them with the current values. Furthermore, we have performed the same procedure for the intra-CEEC trade relations for the all period from 1993 and 2001. However, the ratio of the predicted values over the actual ones is also an indication of the goodness of fit of the model. Indeed, large differences between actual and predicted values may indicate misspecification of the model. Therefore, one should be careful on the analysis of this ratio. Instead of analysing the level of the ratio between predicted and actual values we focus on the evolution over time, as that will provide some information on the trade potential of the countries considered.
The results on the potential versus actual exports from each EU15 country to the total CEEC and from each CEEC to the total EU (15) may be seen in table 10. These show the deepening of the process of trade liberalisation between the CEEC and the EU. There are, however, some differences between EU exports to the CEEC and the CEEC' exports. The results suggest that in global terms the CEEC exports have converged more quickly than the EU exports (17). In particular, there are some indications of the existence of a gap between actual and potential exports to the Czech Republic, Estonia and Romania.
In the long run, given the permanent transformation in CEEC economic structure, it is difficult to predict with confidence the future trade potential. Yet, in spite of the great expansion in the EU-CEEC trade relations, it is expected that the volume of trade will continue to increase due to the expansion of real incomes and to the progress in market reforms in the new members and candidate countries (18). Most studies also suggest that this tendency will not be equal in all countries. The accession of the CEEC to the EU will have in itself a positive effect on bilateral trade flows.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
As we are particularly interested in the relations among the CEEC we present several graphics (see figure 1) with the evolution of the predicted trade flows from each CEEC to the total CEEC over the actual values. The analysis of the results allows us to conclude that not all the countries reveal the same evolution along the time period. While some seem to be getting closer from the potential values of trade along the time for others, particularly after 1997, the gap between potential and actual trade flows is getting bigger (especially in the case of Slovakia, Slovenia and Estonia). In the case of Estonia and Slovakia this is not surprising giving the reduction in trade intensity between these countries and the total CEEC after 1997, which we have analysed in section 2. On the other hand, the fact that most countries seem to be getting closer from potential trade is also according to the developments on trade intensity among these countries.
In the near future, it is expected that trade relations among CEEC will reveal high dynamics and will continue to increase, not only inside each sub-group of countries (CEEC-5, Baltic and Balkans) but also involving all the others. Other authors, like Boillot et al. (2003), have present similar predictions. This is likely to occur due to the recent evolution on these countries trade relations and to the expected decrease in trade costs among these countries. Furthermore, most CEEC already joined EU and it is probable that intra-CEEC trade relations will evolve in similar way to what happened in the previous EU enlargement. In fact, after Spain and Portugal joined the EU bilateral trade relations between the two countries have significantly increased.
5. CONCLUDING REMARKS
EU membership has been promoting a broader market liberalisation and a higher level of economic and monetary stability in the recent members. During the transition process, the dynamics of trade and FDI flows was crucial for the restructuring and modernisation of new members' economies, thus contributing to sustain growth and convergence in the incoming CEEC.
Concerning trade, profound changes in terms of intensity, composition and nature of flows have been taking place. Trade liberalization between the EU and the CEEC has promoted the intensification of bilateral relationships. However, this phenomenon did not affected equally all the partners, as the Central European countries have experienced the major gains. The progressive orientation of CEEC trade relations to the EU coincided with a sharp decline in the intensity of trade among CEEC. Furthermore, CEEC' economic liberalisation has originated significant changes in the productive structures and trade patterns, causing an increasing divergence in the specialization patterns of these countries.
In this paper we used a gravity model to investigate the determinants of total and sectoral trade flows and predict trade potentials among CEEC and EU countries. The estimation results imply that geographical and economic factors have to be taken into account when anticipating the trade impacts of enlargement. Moreover, it is possible to infer that the recent accession of the Eastern countries to the EU will have a positive impact on trade between countries.
The results also highlight distinct determinants of trade for the different sectors and suggest that EU integration and an improvement in physical and technological infrastructures are especially important for the development of trade in R&D sectors.
Another conclusion is that, although potential trade between EU and CEEC is exhausted for most countries in the short-term, there are still some possibilities of trade expansion in other cases. In the long run, in spite of the reinforcement of the EU-CEEC trade relations, the empirical analysis suggests room for further improvement, mainly due to economic development in the new member countries.
A significant issue to consider in the study of potential trade is the relations among the new EU members. Following the abolishment of tariff barriers amongst these countries, changes in intra-CEEC trade dynamics and structures are likely to continue to occur, in line with the developments of previous enlargement processes. In fact, it is possible to conclude that trade within the CEEC will continue to grow faster than that between the EU and new members. This can be seen mostly as a consequence of industrial location strategies of western multinational firms, which have been leading to the emergence of flows between countries of this sub-region.
It is reasonable to believe that an increase in trade intensity will not happen in all sectors. According to previous developments in economic integration experiences, it is possible to anticipate that the increase in trade relations will be higher in industries where the presence of multinationals is more significant and where economies of scale and technology spillover effects prevail. Trade flows will tend to increase as income levels converge, demand structures get more similar and international production networks expand. As a consequence, it is expected that significant changes continue to occur in the comparative advantages patterns, which will depend on the countries position in the European labour division and on their competitiveness performance. In sum, the enlargement triggers trade intensity, reviving old economic partnerships among neighbouring countries which will affect welfare levels, according to their technological knowledge and factor endowments. Even though, in the short and medium term, some countries may experience some negative effects, in the long-term impacts are expected to be positive. In fact, the favourable environment resulting from the economic and monetary stability in the CEEC emerging markets, will generate significant business opportunities, promoting trade expansion for all the countries.
APPENDIX
1. TRADE INDEXES
1. Relative Intensity of Export Index
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
2. Revealed Comparative Advantage Index
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
2. COUNTRIES INCLUDED IN THE ANALYSIS
The EU countries (14 individual countries as Belgium and Luxemburg were considered as one) and 10 CEEC countries), over the period of 1993-2001.
3. DEFINITIONS OF VARIABLES
Dependent variables:
Real Bilateral total Exports from country i to country j. Real bilateral sectoral exports from country i to country j.
Regressors:
GDT--Sum of real GDP from both countries
ED--Economic Distance measured by the absolute value of the difference between the real GDP per capita, between country i and j.
SIM--similarity in country size in terms of GDP, measured using the Balassa and Bauwens (1987) indicator. The variables are in constant values and in US dollars.
Source: Data on GDP, Population and Exports were taken from CHELEM Database.
Dist-geographic distance expressed in kilometres.
(Source: http://www.indo.com/distance/)
Frontier-dummy variable equal to one if the two trading partners share a common border.
EU-dummy variable equal to one when the both trading partners are presently members of the European Union.
CEFTA-dummy variable equal to one when both trading partners are members of CEFTA
Recibido: marzo de 2006; aceptado: agosto de 2006
References
Arellano, M. and Bover, O. (1990): "La econometria de los datos de panel", Investigaciones Economicas, XIV (1), 3-45.
Aussilloux, V. and Pajot, M. (2001): "Trade Issues in European Union Enlargement", Paper on the 75th International Conference: Policy Modeling for European and Global Issues, July, Brussels. Available at http://www.ecomod.net/conferences/ecomod2001/papers_web/ aussilloux_Enlargement%20Ecomod%2001%2007%2020001.pdf.
Baldwin, R. (1994): Towards an Integrated Europe, CEPR, London.
Bertolini, P. and Montanari, M. (2002): "L'integrazione commerciale tra l'UE ed i PECO:un modello di gravita nella prospettiva dell'allargamento", Rivista di Politica Economica, 92(3), 35-56.
Boillot, J.-J. et al. (2003) : "Quel Avenir au Commerce Intra-Peco? Une Analyse Actuelle et Previsionnelle des Echanges en Europe Centrale et Orientale", DREE-MINEFI. Available at http://www.dree.org/elargissement/RapportsSite/EchIntraVF.pdf.
Breuss, F. and Egger, P. (1999): "How Reliable are Estimations of East-West Trade Potentials Based on Cross-section Gravity Analysis?", Empirica, 26 (2), 81-94.
Buch, C. and Piazolo, D. (2000): "Capital and Trade Flows in Europe and the Impact of Enlargement", Kiel Working Paper 1001, University of Kiel.
Caetano, J., Galego, A. Vieira, C., Vieira, I. and Vaz, E. (2004): The European Union's Fifth Enlargement: Effects on Trade and Foreign Investment, Celta Editora, Oeiras.
Cheng, I-H. and Wall, H. (2005): "Controlling for Heterogeneity in Gravity Models of Trade", The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, 87(1), 49-63.
Egger, P. and Pfaffermayr, M. (2003): "The Proper Econometric Specification of the Gravity Equation: a Three-Way Model with Bilateral Interaction Effects", Empirical Economics, 28(3), 571-580.
Egger, P. (2000): "A Note on the Proper Econometric Specification of the Gravity Equation", Economics Letters, 66, 25-31.
Ferragina, A., Giovannetti, G. and Pastore, F. (2005): "A Tale of Parallel Integration Processes: A Gravity Analysis of EU Trade with Mediterranean and Central and Eastern European Countries", IZA Working Paper no 1829.
Festoc, F. (1997): "Le Potentiel de Croissance du Convergence des Pays d'Europe Central et Orientale avec la France e ses Principaux Partenaires", Economie et Prevision, 128, 161-181.
Fidrmuc, J. and Fidrmuc, J. (2003): "Disintegration and Trade ", Review of International Economics, 11 (5), 811-829.
Fontagne, L., Freundenberg, M. and Pajot, M. (1999): "Le Potentiel d'Echanges entre l'Union Europeenne et les PECO", RevueEconomique, 50 (6), 1139-1168.
Fontoura, P., Enrique, M.-G. and Proenga, I. (2005): "Trade Potential in an Enlarged European Union: A Recent Approach", International Trade 0508011, EconWPA.
Gros, D. and Gonciarz, A. (1996): "A Note on the Trade Potential of Central and Eastern Europe", European Journal of Political Economy, 12, 709-721.
Hamilton, C. and Winter, A. (1992): "Opening Up International Trade with Eastern Europe", Economic Policy, 14, 77-116.
Kaitila, V. (2001): "Accession Countries' Comparative Advantage in the Internal Market: A Trade and Factor Analysis", BOFIT Discussion Papers no. 3. Available at http://www.bof.fi/bofit/eng/6dp/abs/pdf/dp0301.pdf.
Kaminski, B. (2001): "How Accession to the European Union has Affected External Trade and Foreign Direct Investment in Central European Economies", World Bank Working paper 2578.
Krugman, P. (1991): "Increasing Returns and Economic Geography", Journal of Political Economy, 99(3), 483-99.
Jakab, Z. et al. (2001): "How Far Has Trade Integration Advanced?: An Analysis of the Actual and Potential Trade of Three Central and Eastern European Countries", Journal of Comparative Economics, 29, 276-292.
Landesmann, M. (2003): "Structural Features of Economic Integration in an Enlarged Europe: Patterns of Catching-up and Industrial Specialisation", European Commission Economic Papers, 181, Brussels.
Linder, S. (1961): An Essay on Trade and Transformation, John Wiley and Sons, New York.
Marques. H. and Metcalf, H. (2005): "What Determines Sectoral Trade in the Enlarged EU?", Review of Development Economics, 9 (2), 197-231.
Matyas, L. (1997): "Proper Econometric Specification of the Gravity Model", World Economy, 20(3), 363-368.
Matyas, L. (1998): "The Gravity Model: Some Econometric Considerations", World Economy, 21(3), 397-401.
Nilsson, L. (2000): "Trade Integration and the EU Economic Membership Criteria", European Journal of Political Economy, 16, 807-827.
Jose Caetano
Universidade de Evora
Jcaetano@uevora.pt
Aurora Galego
Universidade de Evora
agalego@uevora.pt
(1) This work is partially part of previous research performed in the EZONEPLUS project (www. ezoneplus.org), financially supported by the European Commission's Fifth Framework Programme (Contract no HPSE-CT-2001-00084).
(2) We consider in the analysis the following Eastern European countries: Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Slovakia and Slovenia that joined recently the EU and Bulgaria and Romania which are expected to join the EU in some years to come.
(3) According to Boillot et. al. (2003) methodology, the following groups of industries are used: resource intensive; labour intensive; scale and capital intensive; specialised suppliers; R&D intensive.
(4) A detailed analysis on the EU-CEEC trade relations may be seen in Caetano et al. (2004).
(5) Defined as the percentage of external trade on GDP.
(6) The deficits for Germany and Austria could be considered as surprising. However, this consequence of the increasing subcontracting activities between firms in these countries specially under the "Outward Processing Trade" regimes.
(7) The bilateral index "relative intensity of exports" has a three-dimensional nature, and therefore takes into account the evolution registered in the exports of the country of origin and the imports the country of destiny, weighted by the flows of world trade during the period of analysis.
(8) The so-called CEEC5: Hungary, Slovenia, the Czech Republic, Slovakia and Poland.
(9) See Kaminski (2001) or Landesmann (2003).
(10) The index used can be seen in appendix.
(11) In 2001, Hungary had already a clear comparative advantage in R&D and differentiated goods in the trade relations with the EU countries.
(12) This type of products represented about 5% of exports to EU and 31% in 2001.
(13) This may be associated with FDI flows from Finish firms, within the process of production reallocation (Kaitila, 2001).
(14) More detailed information on the data and variables used may be seen in the Appendix .
(15) Central European Free Trade Association, involving Hungary, Slovenia, the Czech Republic, Slovakia, Romania and Poland.
(16) See Egger and Pfaffermayer (2003), Fontagne et al. (1999) and Cheng and Wall (2005)
(17) Bertolini and Montanari (2202) and Fontoura et al. (2005) have reached the same conclusion although applying different methodologies.
(18) See Fontagne et al. (1999) and Auxilioux and Pajot (2001).
TABLE 1: EU MEMBERS TRADE FLOWS WITH CEEC (% OF TOTAL) Weight of CEEC in EU trade 1993 2001 Exp. Imp. Exp. Imp. Germany 4,6 4,5 8,4 8,6 Austria -- -- 12,6 9,5 Bel.-Lux. 1,1 0,7 2,5 2,5 Denmark 2,2 2,5 3,6 4,3 Spain 1 0,6 2,8 1,8 Finland -- -- 6,6 6,0 France 1,4 1,1 3,4 2,7 Greece 6,5 2,1 11,9 3,9 Netherlands 1,7 1,6 3,0 2,4 Ireland 0,4 0,4 1,0 1,4 Italy 3,2 2,5 6,5 4,6 Portugal 0,2 0,3 1,0 0,7 Uni. Kingdom 1,2 0,9 2,1 2,1 Sweden 4,7 4,6 EU 2,5 2,1 5,0 4,3 Share of each EU country in total EU-CEEC trade 1993 2001 Exp. Imp. Exp. Imp. Germany 52,1 56,2 42,4 45,2 Austria -- -- 7,0 6,3 Bel.-Lux. 3,9 3 4,3 4,3 Denmark 2,3 2,6 1,6 1,9 Spain 1,9 1,6 3,0 2,9 Finland -- -- 2,6 2,1 France 9,2 8,4 10,7 9,7 Greece 1,6 1,7 1,1 1,2 Netherlands 6,3 6,5 4,7 4,4 Ireland 0,4 0,3 0,8 0,7 Italy 15,9 12,9 13,9 11,2 Portugal 0,1 0,2 0,2 0,3 Uni. Kingdom 6,4 6,6 4,9 6,9 Sweden 2,8 2,9 EU 100 100 100 100 Source: Own Calculations based on CHELEM database - CEPII. TABLE 2: RELATIVE INTENSITY OF EXPORT INDEX IN BILATERAL TRADE CEEC 1993 2001 France 0,73 1,14 Bel-Lux 0,6 0,84 Germany 2,4 2,83 Italy 1,63 2,19 Netherlands 0,77 1,02 United Kingdom 0,65 0,71 Ireland 0,21 0,34 Denmark 1,14 1,20 Finland 2,23 2,20 Sweden 1,1 1,57 Austria 5,12 4,22 Spain 0,51 0,96 Greece 3,24 3,99 Portugal 0,12 0,32 European Union 1,41 1,68 EU 1993 2001 Slovenia 1,64 1,67 Estonia 1,33 1,77 Latvia 1,48 1,66 Lithuania 0,92 1,44 Bulgaria 0,86 1,39 Czech Republic 1,33 1,81 Slovakia 0,84 1,56 Hungary 1,54 1,84 Poland 1,77 1,82 Romania 1,07 1,80 CEEC 1,39 1,76 Source: Own Calculations based on CHELEM database - CEPII. TABLE 3: HIERARCHY OF RELATIVE INTENSITY OF EXPORT INDEX 1993 Order Exporter Importer Value 1 Finland Estonia 49,80 2 Estonia Finland 32,09 3 Greece Bulgaria 27,30 4 Austria Hungary 10,02 5 Estonia Sweden 9,67 6 Bulgaria Greece 8,83 7 Austria Slovenia 8,73 8 Sweden Estonia 7,57 9 Hungary Austria 7,11 10 Latvia Denmark 6,59 643 Portugal Slovakia 0,05 644 Portugal Poland 0,04 645 Lithuania Ireland 0,04 646 Portugal Latvia 0,02 647 Estonia Ireland 0,02 648 Latvia Greece 0,02 649 Slovakia U.K. 0,01 650 Slovakia Ireland 0,01 651 Portugal Lithuania 0,01 652 Ireland Slovakia 0,00 2001 Order Exporter Importer Value 1 Greece Bulgaria 44,30 2 Estonia Finland 41,87 3 Finland Estonia 25,91 4 Greece Romania 13,66 5 Bulgaria Greece 13,60 6 Estonia Sweden 12,32 7 Austria Slovenia 9,91 8 Latvia Sweden 8,65 9 Finland Latvia 8,49 10 Sweden Estonia 7,83 643 Portugal Estonia 0,15 644 Estonia Greece 0,15 645 Slovenia Ireland 0,15 646 Slovakia Ireland 0,14 647 Portugal Romania 0,14 648 Slovakia Portugal 0,11 649 Latvia Portugal 0,10 650 Portugal Slovakia 0,10 651 Portugal Slovenia 0,09 652 Lithuania Portugal 0,07 TABLE 4: GROWTH RATE OF RELATIVE INTENSITY OF EXPORT TO CEEC (%) Exporters 1993-97 1997-01 1993-01 Estonia -25,7 -13,6 -35,8 Latvia -4,4 33,7 27,9 Lithuania -42,8 63,8 -6,3 Slovenia 5,1 25,8 32,3 Czech Rep -30,0 -29,2 -50,5 Slovakia -45,7 -27,4 -60,6 Hungary -26,6 -9,2 -33,4 Poland 15,8 20,8 39,9 Romania -35,8 45,9 -6,3 Bulgaria -39,4 23,1 -25,4 CEEC -28,9 -9,6 -35,8 Source: Own Calculations based on CHELEM database - CEPII. TABLE 5: RELATIVE INTENSITY OF EXPORT INDEX AMONG CEEC * (2001) Baltic Balkan Imports\Exports countries CEEC-5 countries CEEC-10 Baltic countries 66,5 1,1 0,2 4,9 CEEC-5 3,1 7,5 3,2 5,3 Balkan countries 0,9 1,8 7,8 1,9 CEEC-10 6,6 5,1 3,1 4,5 Source: Own Calculations based on CHELEM database - CEPII. * We have considered the average of bilateral trade values. TABLE 6: CEEC EXPORTS TO EU BY FACTORS OF PRODUCTION (% OF TOTAL) Natural Scale and Resources Labour Capital 1993 2001 1993 2001 1993 2001 Poland 44,0 30,5 25,3 17,7 20,3 25,6 Hungary 33,6 12,7 27,2 10,4 15,6 20,4 Slovakia 28,9 14,8 26,4 17,4 33,4 43,0 Slovenia 19,7 22,1 30,4 16,3 25,7 32,8 Czech Rep 29,9 15,3 23,9 14,7 27,4 32,6 Bulgaria 40,4 27,6 33,8 41,6 13,7 19,8 Romania 29,4 18,5 51,0 55,4 11,6 9,7 Lithuania 75,5 48,2 11,1 31,9 11,7 11,2 Latvia 85,7 74,8 6,9 16,2 6,3 5,5 Estonia 58,6 45,1 25,6 16,6 10,3 6,3 CEEC 37,0 22,3 27,1 19,5 20,6 24,9 Specialised Suppliers R&D 1993 2001 1993 2001 Poland 9,5 25,0 0,8 1,3 Hungary 21,5 42,9 2,0 13,6 Slovakia 10,3 21,8 1,1 2,9 Slovenia 20,7 25,2 3,6 3,5 Czech Rep 16,4 32,4 2,3 5,1 Bulgaria 9,1 9,5 3,0 1,5 Romania 6,8 15,0 1,1 1,4 Lithuania 1,4 7,6 0,2 1,1 Latvia 0,9 2,7 0,1 0,9 Estonia 5,0 30,4 0,5 1,4 CEEC 13,6 28,2 1,7 5,0 Source: Own Calculations based on CHELEM database - CEPII. TABLE 7: RCA OF EU TRADE WITH CEEC BY FACTORS OF PRODUCTION Natural Scale and Resources Labour Capital 1993 2001 1993 2001 1993 2001 Poland 115,2 87,6 37,6 15,4 -51,8 -40,6 Hungary 100,8 21,3 32,4 -13,4 -73,9 -69,4 Slovakia 66,8 23,9 41,7 17,3 52,9 46,7 Slovenia 11,7 20,3 51,7 0,1 -57,5 -5,6 Czech Rep 74,6 13,6 40,1 14,0 5,0 3,2 Bulgaria 66,8 70,3 65,8 59,3 -54,4 -20,8 Romania 41,6 49,5 113,0 97,6 -43,7 -63,1 Lithuania 186,0 167,4 -17,8 55,8 -69,0 -95,9 Latvia 254,8 284,3 -46,4 0,3 -98,4 -118,5 Estonia 124,5 135,7 36,2 0,5 -64,6 -112,4 CEEC 92,6 51,2 40,6 16,3 -41,7 -35,1 Specialised Suppliers R&D 1993 2001 1993 2001 Poland -66,3 -20,5 -34,7 -41,9 Hungary -27,7 47,7 -31,5 13,8 Slovakia -120,4 -57,2 -41,0 -30,6 Slovenia 4,1 2,4 -10,1 -17,1 Czech Rep -80,8 -12,1 -38,8 -18,7 Bulgaria -52,4 -67,5 -25,9 -41,3 Romania -87,0 -53,6 -23,7 -30,3 Lithuania -75,5 -86,9 -23,7 -40,3 Latvia -86,0 -118,4 -24,1 -47,8 Estonia -69,3 6,9 -26,8 -30,7 CEEC -60,1 -11,2 -31,4 -21,3 Source: Own Calculations based on CHELEM database - CEPII. TABLE 8: CEEEC EXPORTS BY FACTORS AND TECHNOLOGY LEVEL (% OF TOTAL) Intra-CEEC 1993 2001 Var.(%) Factors of Production Natural Resources 33,4 33,1 -0,25 Labour 11,5 10,4 -1,11 Capital and Scale 34,4 36,0 1,56 Specialised Suppliers 14,7 15,8 1,14 R&D 6,0 4,7 -1,34 Total 100 100 Technology Level Low Intensity 51,5 51,1 -0,39 Medium Intensity 32,6 32,7 0,14 High Intensity 15,9 16,2 0,25 Total 100 100 UE 1993 2001 Var.(%) Factors of Production Natural Resources 37,0 22,3 -14,70 Labour 27,1 19,5 -7,60 Capital and Scale 20,6 24,9 4,30 Specialised Suppliers 13,6 28,2 14,60 R&D 1,7 5,0 3,30 Total 100 100 Technology Level Low Intensity 39,3 30,0 -9,27 Medium Intensity 34,9 38,6 3,70 High Intensity 25,8 31,3 5,58 Total 100 100 Source: Own Calculations based on CHELEM database - CEPII. TABLE 9: ESTIMATES OF THE GRAVITY MODEL ON EU/CEEC TRADE FLOWS Natural Capital Variable Resources Labour and Scale Fixed Effects Estimates Coeffic. Coeffic. Coeffic. (Robust SE.) (Robust SE.) (Robust SE) GDT 0.589 (*) 0.652 (*) 0.431 (*) (0.070) (0.076) (0.088) SIM 0.022 (***) 0.056 (*) 0.037 (*) (0.012) (0.012) (0.011) ED -0.073 0.037 -0.285 (*) (0.047) (0.052) (0.056) n 4965 4964 4937 Std. Dev. 0.445 0.475 0.531 Residual F test (all coef. 69.91 (*) 175.91 (*) 148.23 (*) = 0, except constant) Hausman 277.81 (*) 327.88 (*) 459.34 (*) Test Auxiliary Regression EU 2.363 * 2.471 * 2.803 * (0.034) (0.034) (0.047) CEFTA 0.202 * -0.119 ** 0.200 * (0.058) (0.060) (0.063) Dist -1.314 * -1.276 * -1.356 * (0.032) (0.033) (0.048) Frontier 0.800 * 0.633 * 0.656 * (0.049) (0.055) (0.076) Specialised Variable Suppliers R&D All Sectors Fixed Effects Estimates Coeffic. Coeffic. Coeffic. (Robust SE.) (Robust SE.) (Robust SE) GDT 1.001 (*) 0.125 0.658 (*) (0.124) (0.124) (0.062) SIM 0.030 (**) -0.008 0.033 (*) -0.016 (0.018) (0.008) ED -0.305 (*) -0.267 (*) -0.222 (*) (0.068) (0.068) (0.038) n 4933 4885 4968 Std. Dev. 0.619 0.699 0.360 Residual F test (all coef. 230.20 (*) 144.31 (*) 282.40 (*) = 0, except constant) Hausman 185.65 (*) 301.95 (*) 226.15 (*) Test Auxiliary Regression EU 2.024 * 3.732 * 2.354 * (0.041) (0.058) (0.031) CEFTA 0.370 * -1.121 * 0.159 * (0.059) (0.129) (0.051) Dist -1.364 * -1.509 * -1.281 * (0.041) (0.057) (0.031) Frontier 0.420 * 0.299 * 0.513 * (0.061) (0.097) (0.051) All variables are in logs, except for dummies. Time dummies were included but not reported. Variables definition, countries used in regression and data sources can be seen in Appendix. (*) , (**) and (***) denote values significant at 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively. TABLE 10: POTENTIAL VERSUS CURRENT EXPORTS BETWEEN EU AND CEEC (a) (POTENTIAL/CURRENT) EU Exports Origin Country 1993 1997 2001 Austria 0.794 0.775 1.247 Benelux 1.047 0.832 0.993 Denmark 0.880 0.859 1.273 Finland 1.515 1.015 1.926 France 1.080 0.870 0.825 Germany 0.921 0.821 1.029 Greece 0.676 0.921 0.881 Ireland 1.768 0.801 1.048 Italy 1.088 0.959 1.205 Netherlands 0.820 0.809 1.078 Portugal 1.532 0.577 0.747 Spain 1.467 0.880 0.939 Sweden 1.364 0.894 1.617 United Kingdom 0.940 0.722 1.135 Destination Country 1993 1997 2001 Bulgaria 1.088 0.979 0.985 Czech Republic 0.761 1.119 1.046 Estonia 0.986 0.842 1.268 Hungary 1.835 0.873 1.268 Latvia 0.967 0.875 1.030 Lithuania 1.575 0.815 0.969 Poland 1.520 0.700 0.869 Romania 0.909 0.785 1.261 Slovakia 1.046 0.971 0.867 Slovenia 1.255 0.803 0.931 CEEC Exports Origin Country 1993 1997 2001 Bulgaria 1.100 0.980 1.005 Czech Republic 0.685 0.619 0.378 Estonia 2.749 1.232 1.400 Hungary 0.981 0.767 0.600 Latvia 1.038 0.925 1.151 Lithuania 0.978 0.995 0.757 Poland 0.568 0.652 0.478 Romania 1.306 0.966 0.708 Slovakia 1.287 0.875 0.725 Slovenia 0.822 1.046 1.020 Destination Country 1993 1997 2001 Austria 0.750 1.011 0.759 Benelux 1.116 0.442 0.494 Denmark 0.760 0.883 0.671 Finland 0.916 0.936 0.857 France 0.895 0.561 0.503 Germany 0.798 0.763 0.609 Greece 0.879 0.988 0.868 Ireland 0.805 0.468 0.377 Italy 0.933 0.744 0.695 Netherlands 0.713 1.080 0.771 Portugal 1.041 0.638 0.664 Spain 1.227 0.384 0.471 Sweden 1.144 0.765 0.875 United Kingdom 0.876 0.759 0.665 (a) These results were obtained using the estimates from the specification considering total exports.
![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() | |
Author: | Caetano, Jose; Galego, Aurora |
---|---|
Publication: | Revista de Economia Mundial (Magazine of World Economy (ies) |
Article Type: | Report |
Date: | Jun 1, 2006 |
Words: | 8765 |
Previous Article: | Tres visiones eticas de la economia: Galbraith, Drucker y Ghoshal. |
Next Article: | La inversion en I+D del sector privado en la UE y en otros paises: un analisis comparativo basado en una clasificacion del 2004 de la Comision... |