Printer Friendly

Farm, Shop, Landing: the Rise of a Market Society in the Hudson Valley, 1780-1860.

By Martin Bruegel (Durham, NC: Duke University Press, 2002. xiii plus 305 pp. $64.95 [cloth], $21.95 [paper]).

A decade ago, and for over a decade before that, as part of a wider discussion of the emergence of American capitalism, there was an intermittent debate about the character and significance of rural exchange and markets in early America. Two main things happened to this debate. On one hand, after doing a substantial amount to recover an understanding of rural life, especially in the eighteenth and early nineteenth century Northeast, various protagonists found that there was relatively little disagreement left between them. On the other, in part through the influence of Charles Sellers' 1991 volume The Market Revolution: Jacksonian America, 1815-1846, attention was switched from rural societies to a broader, national canvas and the concept of a "market revolution" in this period fixed in contemporary historical discourse. That concept has, in its turn, undergone two fates. Many established scholars have been skeptical. A generation of younger historians, by contrast, has taken the "market revolution" as a stepping-off point for exploring the rich array of sources that can illuminate early Americans' economic, social, and cultural lives. Martin Bruegel's work both addresses the earlier debate about rural societies and provides material that will contribute to the discussion of a "market revolution."

As author of locally-based studies that formed part of the original debate, I have an interest to declare. My admiration for this book is formed by my own concern to see historians trace the processes of social and economic change as they grew from, and in turn influenced, the lives of the men and women who lived through them. In addressing what he calls "the construction of a market society" (p. 226) from the perspectives of the farm families, storekeepers, and merchants of the Hudson River Valley, Bruegel adds notably to our understanding of how and why a new way of life came about in the two generations following the American Revolution. His account deserves attention from all historians interested in understanding how, in concrete terms, social change came about and was experienced.

Bruegel's subjects lived in the mid-Hudson Valley counties of Columbia and Greene, which lie respectively east and west of the great river as it flows south from Albany towards New York City. He argues that their economic activities and ways of doing things changed substantially over this period. Population growth, soil exhaustion, competition from newly-emigrated "western" farmers, and the massive expansion of demand from New York, all influenced crop-raising, household activities, and the ways in which farm families used and traded goods. At one level, Bruegel traces quantifiable changes in the Hudson Valley's economy: shifts in agricultural output; merchants' involvement in trade and transportation; the various sources of manufacturing development; and the emergence of new patterns of consumption and wealth distribution. But at the same time he offers valuable insights into the conditions that structured or motivated these developments. Late-eighteenth century people faced a world of comparative scarcity in which the risk of disaster led both to cautious strategies and efforts at productive improvements. By the mid nineteenth century they and their successors had built markets that considerably allayed risk, and provided many with modest, but tangible comforts. In the process, as Bruegel's work in account books and other sources reveals, they had altered many aspects of their own relationships with each other. Economic dealings, at first grounded in familial, personal, and local contacts, had become more instrumental and abstracted from personal ties. Changes in production entailed both rearranged gender roles on farms and greater class segmentation among the region's population. At the ideological level, Bruegel suggests, arguments for laissez-faire in commercial dealings took root as tools for restraining the influence of personal ties and preferences, but also came to combat "producerist" claims of equal rights to the fruits of labor.

Like all regional historians Bruegel must deal with local particularities and the problem of typicality. Sensibly, he suggests that the Hudson Valley represented one pattern in a patchwork of variations; it was neither exceptional nor typical, but in its distinctive features contained indications of broader patterns. He provides useful comparative references to other regions, explaining subtle differences between them. Unlike much of New England, for example, the Hudson Valley did not become home to extensive networks of industrial outwork: lower population densities and the availability of improvable land made commercial farming a more viable route to economic security here than in older-settled or less well-endowed areas. Yet there is some unevenness in Bruegel's treatment of such issues. Perhaps because of a shortage of documentation, we learn little about the origins or local connections of the mid-Hudson Valley's early artisan and factory workforce, a majority of whom were U.S.-born until at least 1850. Prominent among the relatively scant mention of religious history is the suggestion that the region was relatively uninfluenced by the Second Great Awakening; if so, it would be useful to have an explanation for so marked a contrast with nearby cities, or with the "burned-over district" further upstate. Above all, there is less discussion than one might expect of the Hudson Valley's manorial system which, especially east of the river, was arguably its most distinctive feature. Bruegel does, of course, refer to manorial tenancy, to the emergence of the Anti-Rent movement, and to the provisions of the 1846 state constitution that paved the way for the system's disappearance, but he does not seem to have integrated them thoroughly with the rest of his argument. Conceivably, it is justifiable to portray agricultural and market developments without special reference to manorial leaseholds; perhaps forms of tenure made less difference to the process or experience of economic change than the other factors Bruegel refers to. But the issue is not directly confronted. Bruegel suggests that the constitutional changes of 1846 stemmed from the laissez-faire ideology that condemned "constraints" on economic activity, but he seems to have missed an opportunity to examine--say by comparing manorial and non-manorial parts of his own region how influential those constraints actually were.

Christopher Clark

University of Warwick
COPYRIGHT 2003 Journal of Social History
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2003, Gale Group. All rights reserved. Gale Group is a Thomson Corporation Company.

Article Details
Printer friendly Cite/link Email Feedback
Author:Clark, Christopher
Publication:Journal of Social History
Article Type:Book Review
Date:Sep 22, 2003
Words:1016
Previous Article:The Cult of the Nation in France: Inventing Nationalism, 1680-1800.
Next Article:The Social Transformation of Eighteenth-Century Cuba.


Related Articles
The seeds of prosperity and discord: the political economy of community polarization in Greenfield, Massachusetts, 1770-1820.
By-employment and agriculture in the eighteenth-century rural Netherlands: the Florijn/Slotboom household.
New York farmers and the market revolution: economic behavior in the mid-Hudson Valley, 1780-1830.
Show calendar. (Farm Show Guide).
Mighty Change, Tall Within; Black Identity in the Hudson Valley.
The Underground Railroad in the Hudson River Valley: a succinct historical composite.
Out of the shadows: African descendants--revolutionary combatants in the Hudson River Valley; a preliminary historical sketch.

Terms of use | Privacy policy | Copyright © 2022 Farlex, Inc. | Feedback | For webmasters |