Printer Friendly

The effects of consumer-directed health plans on health care spending.

ABSTRACT

We use unique data from an insurer that exclusively offers high-deductible, "consumer-directed" health plans to identify the effect of plan features, notably employer contributions to the spending account, on health care spending. Our results show that the marginal dollar contributed by the employer to the spending account is entirely spent on outpatient and pharmacy services. In contrast, out-of-pocket spending was not responsive to the amount the employer contributes to the spending account. Our results represent the first plausibly causal estimates of the components of consumer-driven health plans on health spending. The magnitudes of the effects suggest important health care spending consequences to higher employer contributions to spending accounts. Our findings are most directly relevant to health reimbursement Reimbursement

Payment made to someone for out-of-pocket expenses has incurred.
 arrangement plan designs, though our results are still of value to health savings account A Health Savings Account (HSA) is a tax-advantaged medical savings account available to taxpayers in the United States who are enrolled in a High Deductible Health Plan (HDHP). The funds contributed to the account are not subject to federal income tax at the time of deposit.  plan designs.

INTRODUCTION

Consumer-directed health plans (CDHPs) that feature relatively high deductibles and a tax advantaged account to pay for services received while a deductible That which may be taken away or subtracted. In taxation, an item that may be subtracted from gross income or adjusted gross income in determining taxable income (e.g., interest expenses, charitable contributions, certain taxes).  applies have been growing over the past few years because many employers and insurers view them as a way to control health care costs. A recent survey indicated that 13 percent of employers offered CDHPs in 2008, up from 7 percent in 2006, and 8 percent of workers were enrolled in such plans in 2008, up from 4 percent in 2006 (Claxton et al., 2008). Approximately 26 percent of employers who did not offer a CDHP CDHP Consumer-Directed Health Plan
CDHP Computational Diffie Hellman Problem
 said they were somewhat or very likely to offer such a plan in the next year. In addition, recent anecdotal anecdotal /an·ec·do·tal/ (an?ek-do´t'l) based on case histories rather than on controlled clinical trials.
anecdotal adjective Unsubstantiated; occurring as single or isolated event.
 reports suggest that the economic downturn is causing more families to turn to high deductible CDHPs as a means of cutting their premium expenditures (Alderman ALDERMAN. An officer, generally appointed or elected in towns corporate, or cities, possessing various powers in different places.
     2. The aldermen of the cities of Pennsylvania, possess all the powers and jurisdictions civil and criminal of justices of the
, 2009).

CDHPs are controversial, however, presumably pre·sum·a·ble  
adj.
That can be presumed or taken for granted; reasonable as a supposition: presumable causes of the disaster.
 due to the greater cost sharing associated with them. Greater cost sharing exposes the consumer to greater financial liability and reduces consumer welfare, although it reduces moral hazard Moral Hazard

The risk that a party to a transaction has not entered into the contract in good faith, has provided misleading information about its assets, liabilities or credit capacity, or has an incentive to take unusual risks in a desperate attempt to earn a profit before the
 effects of insurance. Given the greater financial liability associated with a high deductible plan, the role of the tax advantaged account is critical in terms of evaluating the welfare implications of switching from more traditional insurance plans to a CDHP. The tax advantaged account has the potential to buffer consumers from the increased financial liability, but it can undo To restore the last editing operation that has taken place. For example, if a segment of text has been deleted or changed, performing an undo will restore the original text. Programs may have several levels of undo, including being able to reconstruct the original data for all edits  the incentive to reduce unnecessary care (i.e., moral hazard). Surprisingly, despite the large and growing interest in CDHP, relatively little is known about the effects of these plans, particularly the common feature of employer contributions to tax-advantaged spending account, on health care use and spending, and health outcomes.

Specifically, how individuals respond to the cost-sharing features of CDHPs has not been widely studied, and prior studies of CDHPs have several limitations. Past research is commonly based on case studies of a handful of employers or small surveys of employer and employee attitudes and experiences with regard to CDHP (see Lo Sasso et al., 2004; Buntin et al., 2006; Feldman, Parente, and Christianson, 2007; Wharam et al., 2007; Parente, Feldman, and Chen, 2008). External validity External validity is a form of experimental validity.[1] An experiment is said to possess external validity if the experiment’s results hold across different experimental settings, procedures and participants.  is a distinct challenge when examining the experiences of just a few firms. A greater challenge facing prior studies is that they almost uniformly study CDHP as an add-on option to an employer's health plan offerings leading to difficult, if not intractable intractable /in·trac·ta·ble/ (in-trak´tah-b'l) resistant to cure, relief, or control.

in·trac·ta·ble
adj.
1. Difficult to manage or govern; stubborn.

2.
, selection bias. There is reason to suspect that individuals who choose to enroll in a relatively new health insurance product design over familiar alternatives such as a health maintenance organization (HMO HMO health maintenance organization.

HMO
n.
A corporation that is financed by insurance premiums and has member physicians and professional staff who provide curative and preventive medicine within certain financial,
) or preferred provider organization pre·ferred provider organization
n.
Abbr. PPO A medical insurance plan in which members receive more coverage if they choose health care providers approved by or affiliated with the plan.
 (PPO PPO
abbr.
preferred provider organization


PPO Managed care Preferred provider organization, see there Infectious disease Pleuropneumonia-like organism, see there
) are likely to differ on unobservable factors related to their anticipated health care utilization leading to biased inference (logic) inference - The logical process by which new facts are derived from known facts by the application of inference rules.

See also symbolic inference, type inference.
.

We attempt to remedy the shortcomings of the existing literature by employing unique data from an insurance company that offers CDHPs in the small group market. The setting allows us exploit the considerable variation in policy characteristics across and within hundreds of small employers over time. Moreover, the context is one of full replacement with no competing plan options. Therefore, employees have no choice of plan and there is no (adverse) selection at the employee level. Because of the time frame of our study, we nearly exclusively examine health reimbursement arrangement (HRA) benefit designs versus health savings account (HSA) designs. As described below, there are important differences between the designs and HRA findings may not entirely generalize generalize /gen·er·al·ize/ (-iz)
1. to spread throughout the body, as when local disease becomes systemic.

2. to form a general principle; to reason inductively.
 to HSA settings. The focus on the small group market makes this study particularly timely and relevant from a public policy perspective, as small employers represent one of the most dynamic sectors of the economy with respect to job growth and innovation. However, small employers have been noteworthy for their declining rate of offering health insurance in recent years. Some commentators hold out the hope that CDHPs, by offering a potentially lower cost insurance product, may allow more small employers to retain coverage for employees or restore coverage previously eliminated.

A BRIEF HISTORY OF CDHPs

In the late 1990s, after the managed care backlash had slowed the growth of HMOs and other supply-side mechanisms to restrain health care expenditures, discussion turned toward "defined contribution" health care benefits, borrowing the term from the revolution that happened in employer-sponsored pension benefits. The notion originally discussed was employers simply providing employees with a cash payment (or voucher A receipt or release which provides evidence of payment or other discharge of a debt, often for purposes of reimbursement, or attests to the accuracy of the accounts. ) with which to purchase health insurance on their own. While the notion of employers "cashing out" of the provision of offering health insurance benefits to employees never materialized, early work by Gabel, Lo Sasso, and Rice (2002) summarized the essential character of the consumer-directed health care movement and its contrasting relationship with managed care

At its heart, the consumer-driven health care movement seeks to combine incentives with information to enable consumers to make informed choices about non-life threatening health care. Managed care succeeded in restraining RESTRAINING. Narrowing down, making less extensive; as, a restraining statute, by which the common law is narrowed down or made less extensive in its operation.  costs because a third-party (or in some cases, an at-risk physician) was placed in the role of saying "no" to patients. Managed care's effectiveness in constraining con·strain  
tr.v. con·strained, con·strain·ing, con·strains
1. To compel by physical, moral, or circumstantial force; oblige: felt constrained to object. See Synonyms at force.

2.
 costs was also the source of its unpopularity un·pop·u·lar  
adj.
Lacking general approval or acceptance.



unpop·u·lar
. By contrast, consumer-driven health care is an effort to put patients in a position to say "no" to themselves. This can only happen if consumers are not only aware of the true cost, but have a personal stake in the cost, and have sufficient information and confidence to make treatment decisions. (Gabel, Lo Sasso, and Rice, 2002, p. W396)

At that time, the early industry pioneers of CDHP (e.g., Definity Health, Lumenos, and Destiny Health) were offering products that allowed employers to establish notional no·tion·al  
adj.
1. Of, containing, or being a notion; mental or imaginary.

2. Speculative or theoretical.

3.
 (or actual cash) accounts out of which first-dollar coverage of health care spending was provided. Under most plans, unused account dollars were allowed to roll over into the following year. While the reasoning behind the rollover A graphic element in an application or on a Web page that changes its color or shape when the pointer is moved (rolled) over it. See JavaScript rollover. See also n-key rollover.  feature was clear--to avoid a rush to spend dollars late in the policy year--the legal status of allowing employees to roll over unused dollars had not been formally established until the IRS An abbreviation for the Internal Revenue Service, a federal agency charged with the responsibility of administering and enforcing internal revenue laws.  issued an administrative ruling in the summer of 2002 creating the HRA as a legal entity (U.S. Department of Treasury, 2002).

The key features of HRAs are the employer's contribution of notional pretax pre·tax  
adj.
Existing before tax deductions: pretax income.

pretax adj [profit] → vor (Abzug der) Steuern 
 dollars to an account that can be observed and "managed" by the enrollee. Individuals are not able to contribute to these accounts, and as the accounts are notional, interest cannot be earned, nor can the accounts be paid out should the employee leave the company with positive balance in the account, a fact that limits the portability of HRAs. The HRA ruling, in addition to allowing rollover of unused account dollars, preserved a great deal of flexibility in the design of health insurance products. There are no predefined limits on account contributions, deductible levels, or any other common plan characteristic.

The 2003 Medicare Modernization modernization

Transformation of a society from a rural and agrarian condition to a secular, urban, and industrial one. It is closely linked with industrialization. As societies modernize, the individual becomes increasingly important, gradually replacing the family,
 Act (MMA (Microcomputer Managers Association, Inc.) A membership organization with chapters throughout the U.S. that was devoted to educating personnel responsible for personal computers. It disbanded in 1996.

Mma - A fast Mathematica-like system, in Allegro CL by R. Fateman, 1991.
) brought Health Savings Accounts (HSAs) into existence. HSAs are similar to HRAs in many respects, but have a few notable differences. First, contributions to the account are real, not notional, and hence may earn interest and are portable. Minimum deductibles associated with the accounts are limited to $1,150 for single enrollees and $2,300 for families (in 2009), though they may be higher. The total annual tax-preferred contributions cannot exceed the lesser of the deductible or $3,000 for singles or $5,950 for families. Employer and employee contributions and investment income earned on HSA account balances are not taxable to employees. Withdrawals are not taxable, even after retirement, as long as they are used for qualified medical expenses. HSA portability and ability to accumulate tax-free investment income to fund future medical expenses over a long horizon would increase incentives to delay drawing down account balances compared with HRAs.

CONSUMER RESPONSE TO CDHPs

The basic structure of the problem that is faced by enrollees in a CDHP can be represented graphically as in Panel A of Figure 1. The figure shows a stylized styl·ize  
tr.v. styl·ized, styl·iz·ing, styl·iz·es
1. To restrict or make conform to a particular style.

2. To represent conventionally; conventionalize.
 representation of the trade-off between consumption of health care versus all other goods and services In economics, economic output is divided into physical goods and intangible services. Consumption of goods and services is assumed to produce utility (unless the "good" is a "bad"). It is often used when referring to a Goods and Services Tax.  in the context of a CDHP. We assume consumers receive money in a spending account that is earmarked exclusively for the purchase of health care, which in the simple model is not assumed to decrease income. The kinked budget line (ABC) represents the amount of consumption possible given available income and out-of-pocket prices for goods (including health care). The kink points are generated as a result of discontinuities in out-of-pocket prices for health care that result from the CDHP benefit design, the most novel aspect of which is the presence of the account, which we assume in this case is funded exclusively with employer dollars. Under this simple setting, health care purchased with account dollars, region 1 in the figure, is essentially free; the presence of first-dollar coverage via the account may result in an increase in health care consumed relative to traditional plan designs. (1) However, once the account is exhausted consumers face the full price of health care services as indicated with the steeply sloped budget line in region 2 of the figure, often referred to the "doughnut hole." When the deductible is reached another discontinuity dis·con·ti·nu·i·ty  
n. pl. dis·con·ti·nu·i·ties
1. Lack of continuity, logical sequence, or cohesion.

2. A break or gap.

3. Geology A surface at which seismic wave velocities change.
 in out-of-pocket prices faced by enrollees occurs, indicated at point C. At this point the policy reverts to a traditional "major medical" policy in which cost sharing between the insurance company and the enrollee might be 90-10 coinsurance A provision of an insurance policy that provides that the insurance company and the insured will apportion between them any loss covered by the policy according to a fixed percentage of the value for which the property, or the person, is insured.  (up to an out-of-pocket maximum). In the static model some consumers will choose point B, which is displayed in Panel A with the indifference curve Indifference curve

The expression in a graph of a utility function, where the horizontal axis measures risk and the vertical axis measures expected return. The curve connects all portfolios with the same utility.
; other consumers with a greater willingness to pay Willingness to pay (WTP) generally refers to the value of a good to a person as what they are willing to pay, sacrifice or exchange for it. See also
  • Becker-DeGroot-Marschak method
 for health care will choose to locate along other parts of the budget line, for example, in region 3.

Panel B displays an expansion of the spending account (region 1). The effect of the account expansion is to simultaneously shrink the "doughnut hole" (region 2) while shifting up the budget segment in region 3. The additional spending account dollars clearly make the consumer better off as indicated by the outward shift of the budget line, which represents a pure income effect. Most consumers, such as the one displayed in the figure, will likely spend the additional account dollars on health care as indicated by the move from point B to point B'; other consumers who were in region 3, for example, will also clearly spend more on health care as represented by the upward shift in the budget segment in region 3 that occurs because the fewer dollars needed to spent in the doughnut hole as a result of the larger account represent an income effect in region 3. Moral hazard, either ex ante (self-prevention activities) or ex post (health care price changes), are not strictly dealt with in the figures. (2)

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

Enrollees' utilization decisions will be affected by additional considerations beyond those indicated by the simple model above. First, enrollees in general are uncertain about their health care needs in the future. For example, consider an employee who expects to be in region 3 in each year. If by chance his actual spending in the current year is in region 1, he will hoard the money to reduce expected out-of-pocket spending caused by exposure to the doughnut hole in the next year. Thus, while it is tempting to think that all enrollees will deplete de·plete
v.
1. To use up something, such as a nutrient.

2. To empty something out, as the body of electrolytes.
 their account balances on health care (move to point B or B') in each year, it is possible that enrollees will hold back some discretionary spending because of uncertainty about future health care needs (precautionary saving). The intertemporal consideration can be illustrated by thinking of Panel A in Figure 1 as Year 1 and Panel B as Year 2: if consumers did not reach point B in Year 1, they would experience an increase in their accounts as indicated in Panel B in Year 2. Hence, the decision to spend account dollars is tempered by their potential value in reducing exposure to out-of-pocket costs in the next policy year. However, on average (in expectation), all consumers should use all of the money in their spending accounts. A more general model of insurance and spending under uncertainty is presented in Keeler Keel´er

n. 1. One employed in managing a Newcastle keel; - called also keelman ltname>.
2. A small or shallow tub; esp., one used for holding materials for calking ships, or one used for washing dishes, etc.
, Newhouse, and Phelps (1977).

Another complication complication /com·pli·ca·tion/ (kom?pli-ka´shun)
1. disease(s) concurrent with another disease.

2. occurrence of several diseases in the same patient.


com·pli·ca·tion
n.
 is the potential role of learning over time about how to use a spending account efficiently and to make the correct allocation. Given the period of our study, it is likely that this is the first CDHP to which enrollees have been exposed, and a learning curve could be present. In particular, it is likely to take some time for consumers to realize the actual price of health care from which most enrollees in traditional plan designs have been shielded. As consumers gain more experience with pricing and learn to anticipate their own health care needs with greater accuracy, we might expect to see differential relationships between health plan characteristics, such as the size of the spending account, and health care utilization over time. (3)

The final aspect to consider is the role of selection in determining who chooses to enroll in a CDHP. Prior work has found evidence of favorable fa·vor·a·ble  
adj.
1. Advantageous; helpful: favorable winds.

2. Encouraging; propitious: a favorable diagnosis.

3.
 selection when individuals are presented with the option of CDHP alongside traditional plan designs, a fact that has clouded prior estimates of the effects of CDHPs on utilization (Fowles et al., 2004; Parente, Feldman, and Christianson, 2004); the general literature on adverse selection in insurance markets is well summarized by Cohen cohen
 or kohen

(Hebrew: “priest”) Jewish priest descended from Zadok (a descendant of Aaron), priest at the First Temple of Jerusalem. The biblical priesthood was hereditary and male.
 and Siegelman (2010). A distinct advantage of our data and methodological approach is that we will be able to minimize the effect of selection with respect to health care utilization because we focus on full replacement settings. Employees have no choice of plans. Therefore, a major source of potential bias that has plagued previous studies is not relevant to our study. Selection may still occur, however, but if it does it is at the firm level; firms may choose the account size and deductible based on the health care needs of the employees. Below, we discuss how we address this problem.

Other aspects of the CDHPs have familiar effects on consumer behavior. A larger deductible increases the size of region 2 and shifts the budget line in region 3 downward, which will lead to a decrease in spending on health care for those likely to choose region 3 (i.e., sicker people). A lower (consumer) coinsurance rate will flatten the slope of the line in region 3 and result in greater spending for those in region 3. It is clear that the effects of changes in the deductible and coinsurance should be larger for those likely to locate in region 3 than those in region 1. We investigate this hypothesis below using age of enrollee as a proxy for underlying health and expected expenditure.

DATA AND PLAN DESIGN

The data for our study come from a health insurance company that has been selling CDHPs (predominantly pre·dom·i·nant  
adj.
1. Having greatest ascendancy, importance, influence, authority, or force. See Synonyms at dominant.

2.
 HRAs) for several years in the Small group market. (4) The insurer sells CDHPs exclusively on a total replacement basis and almost all firms offer just one plan. (5) Hence, the most obvious form of selection--that by employees across diverse plan options provided by the employer--is not a concern. (6)

The data are health care claims and enrollment information for employers offering a CDHP. We have information on all claims for inpatient inpatient /in·pa·tient/ (in´pa-shent) a patient who comes to a hospital or other health care facility for diagnosis or treatment that requires an overnight stay.

in·pa·tient
n.
, outpatient, and pharmaceutical health care services throughout the policy year. (7) In addition, we also have information on health plan characteristics including spending account "deposits" at the beginning of the insured period, roll-over account balances from the prior year, deductible amount, coinsurance rates for both in- and out-of-network care (the claims data contain an indicator for network status of the provider), out-of-pocket maximum levels, and copayments for pharmaceuticals. Importantly, we also observe when employers alter characteristics of their insurance policy from one year to the next.

We limit the sample to firms with 2 or more years of information because, as we describe below, we focus on within-firm variation to identify the effect of CDHP features on health care spending and utilization. This within-firm focus allows us to control for unmeasured time-invariant firm-specific factors that may be correlated cor·re·late  
v. cor·re·lat·ed, cor·re·lat·ing, cor·re·lates

v.tr.
1. To put or bring into causal, complementary, parallel, or reciprocal relation.

2.
 with plan features and employee health care use (i.e., firm selection). We also limit the sample to firms that had five or more enrollees. In large firms, it is plausible that features of CDHPs are exogenous Exogenous

Describes facts outside the control of the firm. Converse of endogenous.
, but this is less likely to be the case in very small firms. In these settings it is easy to imagine that a single individual's health care use might alter the contribution and benefits policy for all. Therefore, we drop these small firms.

Table 1 presents information on the employer groups in our sample by year. The average group size is roughly constant over time and in the mid-1920s, with a maximum firm size of 809. There are 2,380 company-years representing 959 unique firms meeting our criterion. (8) Note that the insurer displays marked growth in the number of employer groups offering its products over time. Our data go through the third quarter of 2006 and so we do not observe complete year information for firms whose policies began late in 2005. Accordingly, we use only observations that included full policy years (e.g., began no later than August 1, 2005) and this reduces the number of firms by approximately half in 2005 policy year. Nearly 63 percent of the firms are right-censored in that they continue to offer health insurance provided by the insurer beyond the period at which our claims data end; the remaining 37 percent discontinued dis·con·tin·ue  
v. dis·con·tin·ued, dis·con·tin·u·ing, dis·con·tin·ues

v.tr.
1. To stop doing or providing (something); end or abandon:
 offering the insurer's products. We have no information on why the firms discontinued their relationship with the insurer.

Table 2 displays descriptive statistics descriptive statistics

see statistics.
 for individual enrollees by policy year. Again, we observe the pronounced growth in the number of enrollees over time (2005 represents approximately half of the firms). The spending account averaged roughly $900 over the period with a deductible of nearly $1,900. The spending account is measured as the balance at the beginning of the policy year. Thus, the spending account includes three components: the contribution made by the firm, the contribution made by the individual, and the amount of any roll-over from prior years. (9) The deductible, out-of-pocket maximum, and hospital/surgery deductible tended to rise a bit over time; coinsurance rates did not vary a great deal over time. The out-of-pocket maximum was roughly $7,500, and the hospital/surgery deductible averaged $664. Coinsurance on in-network services was roughly 10 percent; coinsurance on out-of-network services was about 33 percent.

Another plan design feature is that the insurer exempts hospital inpatient stays and outpatient surgery Outpatient Surgery, also referred to as ambulatory surgery or same-day surgery, is surgery that does not require an overnight hospital stay. The term “outpatient” arises from the fact that surgery patients may go home do not need an overnight hospital  spending from the spending account and doughnut hole, though any subsequent outpatient follow-up or prescription drugs associated with the inpatient stay or outpatient surgery are still subject to the spending account and doughnut hole. A separate hospital/surgery deductible is applied to such treatment. This intentional in·ten·tion·al  
adj.
1. Done deliberately; intended: an intentional slight. See Synonyms at voluntary.

2. Having to do with intention.
 design feature was aimed at avoiding cases in which such care would quickly exhaust the spending account for most individuals. Such a design is feasible in the context of an HRA, though would not be typical in an HSA context. To reduce incentives to skimp skimp  
v. skimped, skimp·ing, skimps

v.tr.
1. To deal with hastily, carelessly, or with poor material: concentrated on reelection, skimping other matters.

2.
 on the treatment of chronic conditions, a standard feature of the insurance plans c f this insurer exempts approved classes of chronic medicines from the spending account and doughnut hole, allowing such utilization to be treated as a "postdeductible" expenditure; such chronic medications include antihypertensives and cholesterol-lowering drugs. (10) In addition, enrollees are responsible for out-of-pocket copayments based on a $10/$25/$45 (generic/preferred brand/nonpreferred brand) tiered pharmacy benefit. (11) Pharmaceutical copayments cannot be paid from the spending account. The intent of the copayment co·pay·ment
n.
A fixed fee that subscribers to a medical plan must pay for their use of specific medical services covered by the plan.


copayment,
n
 regime despite the presence of the spending account and the doughnut hole is to continue to provide incentives for enrollees to select less costly pharmaceuticals once the deductible has been exceeded.

Table 3 presents summary statistics on health care spending in the sample. Not surprisingly, spending in all categories increased over time. Total health care spending averaged nearly $4,600 over the period, with about $2,700 in outpatient and pharmaceutical spending and $1,800 in inpatient and outpatient surgery spending (with significantly greater variation); of the total, $840 was spent out of pocket by enrollees.

There are two limitations of the data that merit comment. First, we have no contemporaneous con·tem·po·ra·ne·ous  
adj.
Originating, existing, or happening during the same period of time: the contemporaneous reigns of two monarchs. See Synonyms at contemporary.
 comparison group enrolled in a traditional health plan design. Second, we have no pre-CDHP data on utilization of or spending for care for the firms in the data. Small groups typically do not keep the detailed claims data for their employees, and more likely, they would never have occasion to observe detailed claims collected by their insurer. When an employer does not renew its contract with the insurer, we have no information on why the contract was terminated (e.g., the company has chosen to eliminate health insurance benefits, opted for another carrier, or gone out of business). Similarly, we have no information on the reason an individual employee disenrolls from the plan. In light of the above limitations, our empirical methods (discussed in the next section) will take advantage of the variation in plan design within firms over time.

RESEARCH DESIGN

Our objective is to estimate how employee spending on health care changes with the features of CDHPs. Ideally, we would estimate a model such as

[Y.sub.igt] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1][Firm_Account.sub.gt] + [[beta].sub.2][Deductible.sub.gt] + [[beta].sub.3][Co_I[N.sub.gt] + [[beta].sub.4][Co_OUT.sub.gt] + [[beta].sub.5][HS_Deduct de·duct  
v. de·duct·ed, de·duct·ing, de·ducts

v.tr.
1. To take away (a quantity) from another; subtract.

2. To derive by deduction; deduce.

v.intr.
.sub.gt] + [[beta].sub.6]OOP See object-oriented programming.

OOP - object-oriented programming
 [Max.sub.gt] + [gamma] [X.sub.igt] + [[eta].sub.g] + [[epsilon].sub.igt], (1)

where [gamma] is total annual spending for person/family i in company g in year t, Firm_Account is the amount of dollars the firm contributes to the employee's spending account at the beginning of the year, Deductible represents the deductible level after which enrollees are only responsible for coinsurance (Co_IN for in-network care and Co_OUT is the out-of-network care). HS_Deduct is the separate hospital inpatient/outpatient surgery deductible, OOP Max is the out-of-pocket maximum for patient coinsurance-related expenditures, X represents personal characteristics (age, gender, number of dependents, year of tenure in the plan) as well as calendar-year dummies, [eta] is a firm fixed effect, and s is an idiosyncratic id·i·o·syn·cra·sy  
n. pl. id·i·o·syn·cra·sies
1. A structural or behavioral characteristic peculiar to an individual or group.

2. A physiological or temperamental peculiarity.

3.
 error term.

Unfortunately, we do not observe FirmAccount. We observe only the amount in the employee's spending account at the beginning of the year and this can include voluntary contributions. Therefore, we estimate

[Y.sub.igt] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1][Total_Account.sub.igt] + [[beta].sub.2][Deductible.sub.gt] + [[beta].sub.3][Co_I[N.sub.gt] + [[beta].sub.4][Co_OUT.sub.gt] + [[beta].sub.5][HS_Deduct.sub.gt] + [[beta].sub.6]OOP [Max.sub.gt] + [gamma] [X.sub.igt] + [[eta].sub.g] + [[epsilon].sub.igt], (2)

where Total_Account is measured at the employee level and includes the amount contributed by both the employer and the employee. Enrollee choice over contributions to spending accounts poses a challenge to estimating the causal relationship between the spending account level and health care spending. If individuals anticipate greater health care needs and consequently increase the funding of their account balance (adverse selection), we will observe an upward bias in uninstrumented regressions. Conversely con·verse 1  
intr.v. con·versed, con·vers·ing, con·vers·es
1. To engage in a spoken exchange of thoughts, ideas, or feelings; talk. See Synonyms at speak.

2.
, if more risk averse Risk Averse

Describes an investor who, when faced with two investments with a similar expected return (but different risks), will prefer the one with the lower risk.

Notes:
A risk averse person dislikes risk.
 individuals (who may also have better health status) fund their accounts to a greater extent (advantageous selection), we will observe a downward bias in uninstrumented regressions. In addition, to the extent healthier people fail to spend their account balance they will experience greater roll-over of account balances from one year to the next relative to less healthy individuals; such a relationship would also lead to a downward bias.

In order to mitigate the potential bias from endogenous endogenous /en·dog·e·nous/ (en-doj´e-nus) produced within or caused by factors within the organism.

en·dog·e·nous
adj.
1. Originating or produced within an organism, tissue, or cell.
 account balances, we use an instrumental variables (IV) strategy. We instrument for Total_Account using the minimum account balance, which is measured at the beginning of the policy year, among employees in firm g and year t. Further, the minimum account balance is specific to employees in each coverage option: single, employee plus one dependent, employee plus two or more dependents. Hence, to the extent that at least one employee in each coverage option-firm-year cell chooses not to contribute to their account (the calculation excludes roll-over dollars), our approach will represent a reasonable estimate of the firm's contribution to the account. The mean minimum spending account calculated in this manner is roughly half of the average spending account. In addition, there could be a qualitative difference in the effect for cases in which the employer contributes nothing to the account versus contributing something to the account, we allow for a discontinuity for zero dollar contributions. The first stage of the instrumental variables procedure is:

[Total_Accounti.sub.gt] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [a.sub.1][Min_Account.sub.gt] + [a.sub.2][Min_Zero.sub.gt] + [a.sub.3][Deductible.sub.gt] + [a.sub.3]Co_I[N.sub.gt] + [a.sub.4][Co_OUT.sub.gt] + [a.sub.5][HS_Deduct.sub.gt] + [a.sub.6]OOP[Max.sub.gt] + [a.sub.7][Z.sub.gt] + [a.sub.8][X.sub.igt] + [r.sub.g] + [u.sub.igt], (3)

where the model also includes a full set of interaction terms between Min_Account, Min_Zero, and the other plan characteristics (summarized by the vector Z in Equation (3)). The interaction terms use the information provided by other plan features to help predict the (exogenous) spending account, as other features of the CDHPs are likely to be correlated with the size of the employer contribution to the spending account. Equation (3) is used to obtain a predicted value of Total_Account that will be used in Equation (2).

The efficacy of the instrumental variables procedure depends on two conditions: how well Min_Account (and interactions) predicts Total_Account and whether Min_Account is legitimately excludable from Equation (2). The first condition is well satisfied in our data. The minimum account balance in the firm is a strong predictor of the individual spending account balance conditional on other covariates in Equation (3) even when firm fixed effects are included. This would be expected because the firm contributes a common component (perhaps zero) to all employees and this common component will generate a nonzero non·ze·ro  
adj.
Not equal to zero.



nonzero  

Not equal to zero.
 covariance Covariance

A measure of the degree to which returns on two risky assets move in tandem. A positive covariance means that asset returns move together. A negative covariance means returns vary inversely.
 between the minimum account balance in the firm and individual spending account balances.

The validity of the second condition cannot be assessed in an empirically definitive way. Excluding Min_Account from Equation (2) assumes that the firm does not change the amount it contributes to the spending account in response to changes in employee spending or health care use (beyond that measured by general inflation in health care that is absorbed by year fixed effects). This assumption more likely holds in larger groups, and for this reason we exclude the very small groups. In very small employer settings it is difficult to argue that benefit levels are determined exogenously to the health care needs of the employees. In settings with only a few employees it is easy to imagine that a single individual's need might alter the contribution and benefits policy for all. A second assumption underlying the exclusion restriction is that Min_Account is unrelated to changes in individual choices to contribute to the spending that are driven by changes in health. We argue that this is likely. All that is necessary is that we observe an employee in the same part (minimum) of the spending account distribution in each year. Consider a firm that has not changed its contribution to the spending account. In this case, and ignoring learning, we should observe the same minimum spending account for that firm. It does not have to be the same employee, only an employee with the same minimum.

RESULTS

Table 4 presents estimates of the effect of insurance plan features on four types of health care spending: total spending, outpatient/pharmacy spending, out-of-pocket spending, and spending on inpatient/outpatient surgery. For each type of spending, two sets of estimates are presented: OLS OLS Ordinary Least Squares
OLS Online Library System
OLS Ottawa Linux Symposium
OLS Operation Lifeline Sudan
OLS Operational Linescan System
OLS Online Service
OLS Organizational Leadership and Supervision
OLS On Line Support
OLS Online System
 and IV. (12) As discussed, we expect increases in the spending account to have a positive effect on spending. Higher deductibles are expected to decrease spending, as are higher (consumer) coinsurance rates.

We begin with estimates pertaining per·tain  
intr.v. per·tained, per·tain·ing, per·tains
1. To have reference; relate: evidence that pertains to the accident.

2.
 to total spending. OLS estimates indicate that an additional dollar in the spending account is associated with a significant increase of $1.2 of total spending. The corresponding IV estimate is 0.92 and not statistically significant. Both estimates, however, suggests that, in accordance with Figure 1, each additional dollar contributed to the spending account leads to an additional dollar spent on health care. The elasticity associated with these estimates ranges from 0.18 (IV) to 0.24 (OLS). Qualitatively, the OLS and IV results do not differ significantly, which is a finding that is also observed for other types of spending when the precision of the IV estimates is better. Assuming that our exclusion restrictions are valid, this finding suggests that there is not much selection. The selection we are concerned with is time-varying firm-level selection (we condition on firm fixed effects) and/or time-varying individual-level selection (plans are full replacement and employees have no choice). As we noted earlier, the problem of time-varying firm-level selection is mitigated by the exclusion of small firms. Thus, the absence of significant evidence of selection implies that there is not much individual selection--individuals do not seem to be altering their contribution to their accounts in response to changes in their health (spending).

Regarding other plan characteristics, the deductible has a predictable negative effect on total spending: each additional dollar increase in the deductible is associated with a 55 cent decrease in total spending, which corresponds to an elasticity of 0.23. In-network coinsurance paid by the enrollee has a negative effect on total spending: a percentage point increase in the coinsurance rate leads to an $82 decrease in total spending, which corresponds to an elasticity of 0.17. In addition, the hospital inpatient/outpatient surgery deductible is negatively associated with spending. Age, number of dependents, and female gender are all positive correlates of higher spending (not displayed).

The next columns in Table 4 display analogous analogous /anal·o·gous/ (ah-nal´ah-gus) resembling or similar in some respects, as in function or appearance, but not in origin or development.

a·nal·o·gous
adj.
 regressions for outpatient and pharmaceutical spending. The results are similar to the results observed for total spending. We now see that each additional dollar contributed to the spending account is associated with an additional dollar spent predominantly on outpatient care and pharmaceuticals; this is precisely what we would expect given that spending account dollars are only applicable to noninpatient and nonoutpatient surgery care. The coefficients imply an elasticity of spending account dollars to outpatient/pharmacy spending of 0.28 to 0.43. As with the total spending regressions, an increase in the deductible is associated with a decrease in outpatient/pharmacy spending (elasticity of 0.17), and an increase in in-network coinsurance is associated with a decrease in outpatient/pharmacy spending (elasticity of 0.13).

The next columns display regressions for out-of-pocket spending. The theoretical framework does not produce a clear prediction for out-of-pocket spending: while more generous plan features such as a larger spending account or lower deductible, all else constant, should be protective against out-of-pocket expenditures, the additional health care purchases induced by more generous plan features could be accompanied by increased out-of-pocket spending. For example, all prescription drugs have out-of-pocket copayments associated with them that cannot be paid from the spending account. We cannot reject that any plan features have effects on out-of-pocket spending that are significantly different from zero. Most of our IV coefficient coefficient /co·ef·fi·cient/ (ko?ah-fish´int)
1. an expression of the change or effect produced by variation in certain factors, or of the ratio between two different quantities.

2.
 estimates have fairly precise standard errors, though at least in the case of the spending account the standard error does not let us rule out relatively large effect sizes.

The final column of Table 4 displays regression results for hospital inpatient and outpatient surgery spending, which as previously noted is treated differently from other spending under the benefit design in that it is not subject to spending account and deductible considerations. However, there is a separate deductible for inpatient care inpatient care Managed care Services delivered to a Pt who needs physician care for > 24 hrs in a hospital . Despite this, given any complementarities between outpatient and inpatient care are complements, there could exist a positive relationship between the spending account/deductible and inpatient spending. Our findings are consistent with a complementary relationship in that the deductible that should apply only to outpatient care has a negative effect on inpatient care; similarly, there is some evidence of a positive effect of spending account dollars on inpatient care, though the IV estimate is not precisely measured. The hospital/surgery deductible, while negative, is not statistically different from zero.

Theory suggests that aspects of the insurance plan such as the deductible and coinsurance have different effects depending on where enrollees are in the spending distribution. Specifically, the effects of the deductible and coinsurance rates should be greater for individuals more likely to be in region 3 of Figure 1. To examine this, Table 5 displays results that stratify strat·i·fy  
v. strat·i·fied, strat·i·fy·ing, strat·i·fies

v.tr.
1. To form, arrange, or deposit in layers.

2.
 by age 50 or over and less than 50 years of age. (13) In addition, because selection associated with account balances appeared to be minimal, and IV estimates somewhat imprecise im·pre·cise  
adj.
Not precise.



impre·cisely adv.
, we only show OLS results in Table 5.

Estimates in Table 5 are for the most part consistent with theoretical predictions, although standard errors are too large to draw definitive conclusions. Changes in the deductible are associated with larger changes in spending for those over age 50, and presumably healthier and likely to be in region 3 (Figure 1), than for those under age 50. Estimates with regard to coinsurance are mixed with respect to theoretical predictions, but these estimates are quite imprecise.

DISCUSSION

The goal of our research was to identify the effect of features of consumer-directed health insurance policies--notably employer contributions to the spending account--on health care spending. How individuals respond to such cost sharing has not received a thorough treatment since the RAND Health Insurance Experiment The RAND Health Insurance Experiment (RAND HIE) was a comprehensive study of health care cost, utilization and outcome in the United States. It is the only randomized study of health insurance, and the only study which can give definitive evidence as to the causal effects of  (HIE hie  
intr. & tr.v. hied, hie·ing or hy·ing , hies
To go quickly; hasten.



[Middle English hien, from Old English h
) of the mid-1970s (Newhouse, 1994), and the spending account component of the plan design did not exist at that time. Our results show that enrollees tend to treat the marginal dollar contributed by the employer to the spending account as an apparent shift in "permanent income" in that the entire dollar is spent on health care. Outpatient and pharmacy spending was responsive to the size of the spending account, while inpatient spending was not--a relationship in accordance with the design of the benefit. Employer contributions to the spending account and other plan features had no statistically significant effect on out-of-pocket spending.

While the direction of our findings are not necessarily surprising, the magnitudes of the effects suggest important health care spending consequences to higher spending account contributions by employers. An equal increase in the deductible and contribution to a spending account will increase total health care spending. Theoretically, this is because those who expect to spend relatively little (i.e., healthy) spend more than they would under such a change, and those who expect to spend a lot (i.e., sick) are unaffected by an equal change in the account and deductible. In fact, our estimates indicate that, on average, an increase in the deductible that is twice as large as an increase in the spending account would result in no change in total spending. We are unable to identify whether the marginal benefit of the additional care consumed exceeds the marginal cost Marginal cost

The increase or decrease in a firm's total cost of production as a result of changing production by one unit.


marginal cost

The additional cost needed to produce or purchase one more unit of a good or service.
; thus, we cannot comment on whether the increase represents moral hazard. Moreover, because the deductible has relatively little effect on healthy persons, this trade-off between a higher deductibles and a higher spending account has a particularly large effect on spending; estimates indicate that the deductible would have to be raised by almost $4 for every $1 increase in the spending account to keep spending unchanged.

These are important findings because they are in line with theory suggesting that moral hazard is least problematic for services that have an inelastic inelastic

Of or relating to the demand for a good or service when quantity purchased varies little in response to price changes in the good or service.
 demand such as inpatient services. Holding constant the spending account, increases in the deductible are intended to decrease moral hazard among those with large expected expenditures because such an increase will have little effect on those with relatively small expected expenditures (see Figure 1). The upshot of this discussion is that trading a dollar of deductible for a dollar of spending account is a poor idea from the employer's perspective as it will result in increased expenditures, particularly when the enrollee group is composed of younger workers. It will also tend to make sicker persons worse off for little gain, as there will be relatively little reduction in care and thus little reduction in inefficient care (moral hazard).

Our results have important implications for benefit design and for firms considering offering CDH Congenital diaphragmatic hernia (CDH)
A condition in which the fetal diaphragm—the muscle dividing the chest and abdominal cavity—does not close completely.

Mentioned in: Prenatal Surgery
 plans to their employees. Employers need to use caution in deciding on account contribution levels. Some amount of funding for the account may be necessary to induce "buy-in" for a switch to high-deductible policy from employees, but this would need to be weighed against the spending increases prompted by the contribution.

It is not clear the extent to which, we can generalize from the small group market. For example, the small group health insurance market is much more subject to state regulations, some of which prevent insurers from even offering CDHPs. However, there are no compelling reasons why workers at small companies would respond differently to health plan characteristics than workers at large companies. There may also be peculiarities about the employers who decided to offer a CDHP in the first place: why did they choose this product when they did? It is possible that the reasons could be related to the health spending outcomes of interest in this study. In addition, our findings are most directly relevant to HRA plan designs, which in this case lack portability and thus may not be valued as highly by enrollees, though our results are still of value to HSA plan designs in that the plans studied here allow for self-funding by enrollees.

DOI (Digital Object Identifier) A method of applying a persistent name to documents, publications and other resources on the Internet rather than using a URL, which can change over time. : 10.1111/j.1539-6975.2009.01346.x

REFERENCES

Alderman, L., 2009, Advice to the Jobless job·less  
adj.
1. Having no job.

2. Of or relating to those who have no jobs.

n. (used with a pl. verb)
Unemployed people considered as a group. Used with the.
 on Getting Health Coverage, New York New York, state, United States
New York, Middle Atlantic state of the United States. It is bordered by Vermont, Massachusetts, Connecticut, and the Atlantic Ocean (E), New Jersey and Pennsylvania (S), Lakes Erie and Ontario and the Canadian province of
 Times, February 28, B6.

Buntin, M. B., C. Damberg, A. Haviland, K. Kapur, N. Lurie, R. McDevitt, and M. S. Marquis, 2006, Consumer-Directed Health Care: Early Evidence About Effects on Cost and Quality, Health Affairs, 25(6): w516-w530.

Chiappori, P.-A., F. Durand, and P.-Y. Geoffard, 1998, Moral Hazard and the Demand for Physician Services: First Lessons From a French Natural Experiment, European Economic Review, 42: 499-511.

Claxton, G., J. R. Gabel, B. DiJulio, J. Pickreign, H. Whitmore, B. Finder, M. Jarlenski, and S. Hawkins, 2008, Health Benefits In 2008: Premiums Moderately Higher, While Enrollment in Consumer-Directed Plans Rises in Small Firms, Health Affairs, 27(6): w492-w502.

Cohen, A., and P. Siegelman, 2010, Testing for Adverse Selection in Insurance Markets, Journal of Risk and Insurance, 77(1): 39-84.

Dionne, G., and P. St. Michel, 1991, Workers' Compensation and Moral Hazard, Review of Economics and Statistics, 73(2): 236-244.

Feldman, R., S. T. Parente, and J. B. Christianson, 2007, Consumer-Directed Health Plans: New Evidence on Spending and Utilization, Inquiry, 44: 26-40.

Fowles, J. B., E. A. Kind, B. L. Braun, and J. Bertko, 2004, Early Experience With Employee Choice of Consumer-Directed Health Plans and Satisfaction With Enrollment, Health Services Research Health services research is the multidisciplinary field of scientific investigation that studies how social factors, financing systems, organizational structures and processes, health technologies, and personal behaviors affect access to health care, the quality and cost of health care, , 39(4, Part 2): 1141-1158.

Gabel, J., A. T. Lo Sasso, and T. Rice, 2002. Consumer-Choice Plans: Are They More Than Talk Now? Health Affairs, November 20. World Wide Web: http://content. healthaffairs.org/cgi/content/abstract/hlthaff.w2.395v1.

Lo Sasso, A. T., T. Rice, J. Gabel, and H. Whitmore, 2004, Tales From the New Frontier New Frontier

President John F. Kennedy’s legislative program, encompassing such areas as civil rights, the economy, and foreign relations. [Am. Hist.: WB, K:212]

See : Aid, Governmental
: Pioneers' Experiences With Consumer-Driven Health Care, Health Services Research, 39(4, Part 2): 1071-1089.

Newhouse, J. R, and The Insurance Experiment Group, 1994. Free for All? Lessons from the RAND Health Insurance Experiment (Cambridge, MA.: Harvard University Press The Harvard University Press is a publishing house, a division of Harvard University, that is highly respected in academic publishing. It was established on January 13, 1913. In 2005, it published 220 new titles. ).

Parente, S. T., R. Feldman, and S. Chen, 2008, Effects of a Consumer Driven Health Plan on Pharmaceutical Spending and Utilization, Health Services Research, 43(5): 1542-1556.

Parente, S. T., R. Feldman, and J. B. Christianson, 2004. Evaluation of the Effect of a Consumer-Driven Health Plan on Medical Care Expenditures and Utilization, Health Services Research, 39(4, Part 2): 1189-1210.

U.S. Department of Treasury, 2002, Internal Revenue Service Notice 2002-45; Rev. Rul. 2002-41.

Wharam, J. F., B. E. Landon, A. A. Galbraith, K. P. Kleinman, S. B. Soumerai, and D. Ross-Degnan, 2007, Emergency Department Use and Subsequent Hospitalizations Among Members of a High-Deductible Health Plan, JAMA, 297(10): 1093-1102.

(1) In equilibrium with perfectly elastic labor demand, the incidence of changes in the spending account will fall entirely on employees in the form of lower wages. For simplicity in the description we abstract from this issue.

(2) The RAND study did not find evidence of ex ante moral hazard (Newhouse, 1994). Prior work has examined ex post moral hazard with success in health care and other insurance settings (e.g., Chiappori, Durand, and Geoffard, 1998; Dionne and St. Michel, 1991).

(3) We estimated models that allowed us to look separately at the effect of the account balance in the first year of enrollment versus subsequent years. We were generally not able to reject that the first-year coefficient differed from coefficient for subsequent years. We do not present these findings, but the results are available by request.

(4) In principle, we might expect individuals to place a greater value on dollars in an HSA given the portability they afford relative to HRAs. In our data, however, only roughly 2 percent of firms offered HSAs so we are unable to test this hypothesis.

(5) A small number of employers offered more than one plan design to employees in the study period. Most commonly, employees could select a higher or lower deductible option, but this only occurred in 3 percent of employers. The presence of multiple plan options can introduce selection concerns as individuals might select plans based on anticipated health care needs. The results reported below did not change appreciably ap·pre·cia·ble  
adj.
Possible to estimate, measure, or perceive: appreciable changes in temperature. See Synonyms at perceptible.
 when these employers were excluded from the sample.

(6) More subtle forms of selection are possible. For example, individuals may decide to drop or not take up in the first place offered health insurance and instead take advantage of coverage provided by a spouse or parent. Such selection would change the composition of employees in the firm over time.

(7) One concern is that enrollees will have reduced incentives to file claims for care for which there is no reimbursement. However, for enrollees to take advantage of provider network discounts they must display their insurance cards and the provider is then responsible for submitting claims to the insurer. In addition, consumers have an incentive to have spending recorded by the insurer in order more readily to meet the deductible. As a result, it is unlikely that enrollees will fail to report health care activity while in the doughnut hole.

(8) In the full sample including the very small groups and the firms with only 1 year of data there are 4,463 company-years representing 2,234 unique firms.

(9) The data do not allow us to distinguish between employer and employee contributions to the account.

(10) In more recent years, employers were allowed the option of not treating chronic medicines any different from other types of utilization. However, very few groups chose to offer policies without the chronic rider.

(11) The copayment schedule began as $10/$20/$45 and was switched for all enrollees in 2003 to $10/$25/$45. In more recent years, employers had the option of instituting a $15/$35/$60 copayment regime.

(12) In addition, we estimated two-part models that allow us to distinguish between effects on the extensive margin and the intensive margin. We found generally symmetric No difference in opposing modes. It typically refers to speed. For example, in symmetric operations, it takes the same time to compress and encrypt data as it does to decompress and decrypt it. Contrast with asymmetric.

(mathematics) symmetric - 1.
 results for plan characteristics across both margins. As an additional sensitivity analysis, we estimated models that excluded that excluded the top 5 percent of the spending distribution and found that our results were generally quite similar in magnitude. Results are available by request.

(13) The stratification stratification (Lat.,=made in layers), layered structure formed by the deposition of sedimentary rocks. Changes between strata are interpreted as the result of fluctuations in the intensity and persistence of the depositional agent, e.g.  is not perfect as older workers may have younger dependents on their policy. Keeler, E. B., J. P. Newhouse, and C. E. Phelps, 1977, Deductibles and the Demand for Medical Care Services: The Theory of a Consumer Facing a Variable Price Schedule Under Uncertainty, Econometrica, 45(3): 641-655.

Anthony T. Lo Sasso and Lorens A. Helmchen are in the Division of Health Policy and Administration, School of Public Health, University of Illinois at Chicago This article is about the University of Illinois at Chicago. For other uses, see University of Illinois at Chicago (disambiguation).

UIC participates in NCAA Division I Horizon League competition as the UIC Flames in several sports, most notably Basketball.
 and Institute of Government and Public Affairs Those public information, command information, and community relations activities directed toward both the external and internal publics with interest in the Department of Defense. Also called PA. See also command information; community relations; public information. , University of Illinois University of Illinois may refer to:
  • University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign (flagship campus)
  • University of Illinois at Chicago
  • University of Illinois at Springfield
  • University of Illinois system
It can also refer to:
. Anthony T. Lo Sasso can be contacted via e-mail: losasso@uic.edu. Robert Kaestner is in the Institute of Government and Public Affairs, University of Illinois and Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago. We gratefully acknowledge numerous helpful suggestions from Tom Buchmueller, Roger Feldman, Scott Harrington Scott Harrington (born December 24, 1963 in Louisville, Kentucky) is a former driver in the Indy Racing League. Starting out on two wheels, Harrington won a number of championships and achieved much success in the world of AMA Motocross and Supercross. , Will Manning, Steve Parente, and seminar participants at the American Economic Association annual meeting, the Academy Health annual research meeting, Rochester University, the Southeastern Health Economics Study Group, IUPUI IUPUI Indiana University-Purdue University Indianapolis (Indianapolis, IN, USA) , Lehigh University Lehigh University, at Bethlehem, Pa.; coeducational; chartered and opened 1866 by Asa Packer. It has undergraduate colleges of arts and science, business and economics, and engineering and applied science, as well as several graduate programs. , Tulane University History
Founding/early history
The University dates from 1834 as the Medical College of Louisiana.<ref name="facts" /> With the addition of a law department, it became The University of Louisiana
, University of Illinois at Chicago, University of Minnesota (body, education) University of Minnesota - The home of Gopher.

http://umn.edu/.

Address: Minneapolis, Minnesota, USA.
, and the National Economists Club in Washington DC. Expert research assistance was provided by Sara Borelli and Kevin Callison.
TABLE 1
Descriptive Statistics of Enrollment by Year

                               Policy Year Beginning

                          2000     2001     2002     2003

Total enrollment          28.7     29.0     23.4     24.4
  (standard deviation)   (28.7)   (43.0)   (28.7)   (41.5)
Min (b)                    7        5        5        5
Max                        69      210      211      809
N [Employers/Groups]       6        7       323      579
N [Enrollees]             172     2,032    7,551    14,131

                          Policy Year Beginning

                                   2005
                          2004     (a)     Total

Total enrollment          23.7     23.1     23.9
  (standard deviation)   (33.2)   (39.3)   (36.6)
Min (b)                    5        5        5
Max                       599      679      809
N [Employers/Groups]      830      572     2,380
N [Enrollees]            19,706   13,217   56,809

(a) Includes only employers whose policy years began no
later than August 1, 2005.

(b) Sample only includes firms with five or more enrollees.

TABLE 2
Descriptive Statistics of Enrollee and Plan Characteristics Over Time

                                        Policy Year Beginning

                                 2000      2001      2002      2003

Plan characteristics
  Spending account                672       823       857       859
                                 (864)     (702)     (697)     (722)
  Deductible                     3,902     1,733     1,629     1,886
                                (4,048)   (1,359)    (932)    (1,313)
  OOP max                        5,000     5,960     6,253     7,616
                                  (0)     (1,970)   (2,554)   (4,415)
  In-network coinsurance         13.8       9.7      10.4       9.4
                                 (5.2)     (5.5)     (5.8)     (6.7)
  Out-of-network coinsurance     33.8      29.7      31.0      34.4
                                 (5.2)     (5.5)     (6.3)     (8.9)
  Hospital/surgery deductible      0        327       470       787
                                  (0)      (282)     (332)    (1,082)
Enrollee characteristics
  Age                            42.7      38.5      40.2      40.0
                                (12.3)    (11.6)    (12.0)    (12.1)
  Female                         0.53      0.36      0.38      0.37
  Tenure in plan                   1       1.06      1.22      1.46
                                  (0)     (0.24)    (0.45)    (0.63)
  Single                         0.66      0.54      0.53      0.55
  Employee+1                     0.12      0.16      0.18      0.17
  Employee+2                     0.22      0.30      0.39      0.28
  Number of dependents           0.84      1.11      1.07      1.04
                                (1.48)    (1.53)    (1.46)    (1.44)
N                                 172      2,032     7,551    14,131

                                   Policy Year Beginning

                                 2004      2005a     Total

Plan characteristics
  Spending account                886      1,006      901
                                 (784)     (891)     (785)
  Deductible                     1,903     1,938     1,870
                                (1,186)    (978)    (1,180)
  OOP max                        7,609     7,851     7,420
                                (4,212)   (4,488)   (4,127)
  In-network coinsurance          9.5       8.7       9.4
                                 (6.7)     (6.7)     (6.6)
  Out-of-network coinsurance     34.1      33.9      33.5
                                 (8.6)     (9.1)     (8.6)
  Hospital/surgery deductible     669       696       664
                                 (883)    (1,004)    (910)
Enrollee characteristics
  Age                            40.8      41.6      40.6
                                (12.0)    (12.1)    (12.1)
  Female                         0.39      0.40      0.39
  Tenure in plan                 1.73      2.29      1.70
                                (0.85)    (0.86)    (0.83)
  Single                         0.55      0.54      0.54
  Employee+1                     0.17      0.17      0.17
  Employee+2                     0.28      0.29      0.29
  Number of dependents           1.04      1.05      1.05
                                (1.43)    (1.42)    (1.44)
N                               19,706    13,217    56,809

Notes: Family coverage is treated as one insurance unit. OOP
max is out-of-pocket maximum for patient coinsurance-related
expenditures. Standard deviations are presented in parentheses.

(a) Includes only employers whose policy years began no later
than August 1, 2005.

TABLE 3
Descriptive Statistics of Health Care Spending

                                        Policy Year Beginning

                                2000       2001       2002       2003

Total health care spending      2,313     4,199      4,534      4,297
                               (4,957)   (16,823)   (16,473)   (14,283)
Total OP/Rx spending            1,562     2,550      2,638      2,645
                               (2,875)   (10,144)   (5,234)    (7,132)
Total IP/OP surgery spending     750      1,650      1,896      1,652
                               (2,869)   (9,115)    (13,598)   (10,247)
Total out-of-pocket spending     670       704        764        899
                               (1,178)   (1,277)    (1,705)    (5,288)
N [Enrollees]                    172      2,032      7,551      14,131

                                   Policy Year Beginning

                                 2004       2005      Total

Total health care spending      4,445      5,172      4,574
                               (14,919)   (15,210)   (15,105)
Total OP/Rx spending            2,650      3,040      2,731
                               (5,122)    (5,418)    (5,997)
Total IP/OP surgery spending    1,795      2,132      1,843
                               (12,172)   (12,382)   (11,865)
Total out-of-pocket spending     812        885        840
                               (1,454)    (1,701)    (2,969)
N [Enrollees]                   19,706     13.217     56,809

Notes: Family coverage is treated as one insurance
unit. Standard deviations are presented in  parentheses.

TABLE 4
Estimates of the Effect of Plan
Characteristics on Health Care Spending

                                                   Outpatient/
                       Total Spending           Pharmacy Spending

                      OLS           IV          OLS           IV

Spending              1.23         0.92         0.86         1.29
  account          (0.17) **      (0.84)     (0.08) **    (0.41) **
Deductible           -0.55        -0.56        -0.26        -0.25
                   (0.13) **    (0.13) **    (0.06) **    (0.06) **
In-network           -82.13       -82.69       -39.63       -38.83
  coinsurance      (31.43) **   (31.64) **   (12.79 **    (12.58) **
Out-of-network        7.25         6.66        -11.63       -10.79
  coinsurance       (26.19)      (26.60)      (12.64)       (12.72
Hospital/surgery     -0.29        -0.30        -0.22        -0.21
  deductible        (0.13) *     (0.13) *     (0.10) *      (0.10
OOP max              -0.01        -0.01         0.02         0.01
                     (0.05)       (0.05)       (0.02)       (0.02)
Mean of dep.         $4,574                    $2,731
  variable

                        Out-of-Pocket        Inpatient/Outpatient
                      Spending Surgery              Spending

                      OLS           IV          OLS           IV

Spending              0.04        -0.22         0.37        -0.37
  account            (0.05)       (0.24)     (0.12) **      (0.59)
Deductible            0.02         0.02        -0.29        -0.31
                     (0.03)       (0.04)     (0.08) **    (0.08) **
In-network            1.03         0.54        -42.50       -43.86
  coinsurance        (4.73)       (4.83)      (27.49)      (27.95)
Out-of-network        5.41         4.90        18.89        17.45
  coinsurance        (3.83)       (3.93)      (18.37)      (18.59)
Hospital/surgery      0.01         0.01        -0.08        -0.08
  deductible         (0.05)       (0.05)       (0.05)       (0.06)
OOP max               0.01         0.01        -0.02        -0.02
                     (0.01)       (0.01)       (0.04)       (0.04)
Mean of dep.          $840                     $1,843
  variable

Notes: n = 56,809 observations in 959 employers. Regressions
control for age, gender, coverage type (employee, employee+1,
employee+2 or more), number of dependents, calendar year, tenure
(year) of enrollment, and firm fixed effects. IV regressions use
the following variables as instruments: company-year minimum of
spending account balance, indicator for minimum account = 0, and
interactions between these two variables and deductible, in-network
coinsurance, out-of-network coinsurance, hospital-surgery deductible,
and OOP maximum. The first-stage partial F-statistic is 18.8.
The Sargan-Hansen J-test of overidentifying restrictions was 11.25
(p = 0.42) for total spending, 19.11 (p = 0.06) for outpatient-pharmacy
spending, 23.02 (p = 0.02) for out-of-pocket spending, and 10.79
(p = 0.46) for inpatient spending. Robust standard errors controlling
for employer-level clustering in parentheses: * significant
at 5%; ** significant at 1%.

TABLE 5
Estimates of the Effect of Plan Characteristics on
Health Care Spending for Older and Younger Workers

                                                  Outpatient/
                         Total Spending           Pharmacy Spending

Age Group:                  >50         <50          >50         <50

Spending account           1.12         1.40        0.92        0.90
                         (0.32) **   (0.18) **    (0.12) **   (0.09) **
Deductible                 -0.72       -0.42        -0.27       -0.26
                         (0.17) **    (0.21) *    (0.05) **   (0.11) *
In-network coinsurance    -62.48       -90.23      -61.60      -31.07
                          (99.73)    (24.88) **   (27.29) *   (12.24) *
Out-of-network             44.02       -3.01        4.32       -14.08
  coinsurance             (77.01)     (23.18)      (28.38)     (12.33)
Hospital/surgery           0.04        -0.32        0.00        -0.24
  deductible              (0.68)     (0.11) **     (0.22)     (0.09) *
OOP max                    -0.12        0.04        -0.06       0.04
                          (0.14)       (0.06)      (0.05)      (0.02)
Observations              14,554       42,255      14,554      42,255
Mean of dep. variable     $7,237       $3,657      $4,107      $2,257

                         Out-of-Pocket     Inpatient/Outpatient
                         Spending Surgery  Spending

Age Group:                >50      <50        >50         <50

Spending account          0.05     0.06      0.20         0.50
                         (0.04)   (0.06)    (0.23)     (0.13) **
Deductible                0.00     0.04      -0.45       -0.17
                         (0.03)   (0.04)   (0.14) **     (0.12)
In-network coinsurance    0.36     1.35      -0.88       -59.16
                         (9.40)   (4.34)    (86.73)    (19.45) **
Out-of-network            7.41     4.32      39.70       11.06
  coinsurance            (7.77)   (3.47)    (58.45)     (15.26)
Hospital/surgery          0.12     0.00      0.04        -0.08
  deductible             (0.09)   (0.04)    (0.57)      (0.04) *
OOP max                   0.01     0.01      -0.06        0.00
                         (0.02)   (0.01)    (0.11)       (0.04)
Observations             14,554   42,255    14,554       42,255
Mean of dep. variable    $1,228    $706     $3,130       $1,400

Notes: OLS regressions are displayed. There are 959 employers for
the <50 regressions and 853 employers for the >50 regression.
Regressions control for age, gender, coverage type (employee,
employee+1, employee+2 or more), number of dependents, calendar
year, tenure (year) of enrollment, and firm-fixed effects. Robust
standard errors controlling for employer-level clustering in
parentheses: * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%.
COPYRIGHT 2010 American Risk and Insurance Association, Inc.
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2010 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.

 Reader Opinion

Title:

Comment:



 

Article Details
Printer friendly Cite/link Email Feedback
Author:Lo Sasso, Anthony T.; Helmchen, Lorens A.; Kaestner, Robert
Publication:Journal of Risk and Insurance
Geographic Code:1USA
Date:Mar 1, 2010
Words:9172
Previous Article:Testing for adverse selection in insurance markets.
Next Article:The effects of offering health plan choice within employment-based purchasing groups.
Topics:

Terms of use | Copyright © 2014 Farlex, Inc. | Feedback | For webmasters