Printer Friendly

Statement to the Congress.

Statement by Alan Greenspan, Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, before the Subcommittee on Economic Growth and Credit Formation of the Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs, U.S. House of Representatives, July 20, 1993

Thank you for this opportunity to discuss the Federal Reserve's semiannual monetary policy report to the Congress.(1) My remarks this morning will cover current monetary policy and economic settings as well as the Federal Reserve's longer-term strategy for contributing, to the best of its abilities, to the nation's economic well-being.

As economic expansion has progressed somewhat fitfully, our earlier characterization of the economy as facing stiff headwinds has appeared increasingly appropriate. Doubtless the major headwind in this regard has been the combined efforts of households, businesses, and financial institutions to repair and rebuild their balance sheets after the damage inflicted in recent years as weakening asset values exposed excessive debt burdens.

But there have been other headwinds as well. The builddown of national defense has cast a shadow over particular industries and regions of the nation. Spending on nonresidential real estate dropped dramatically in the face of overbuilding and high vacancy rates and has remained in the doldrums. At the same time, corporations across a wide range of industries have been making efforts to pare employment and expenses to improve productivity and their competitive positions. These efforts have been prompted, in part, by innovative technologies that have been applied to almost every area of economic endeavor and have boosted investment. However, their effect on jobs and wages through much of the expansion has also made households more cautious spenders.

In the past several years, as these influences have restrained the economy they have been balanced, in part, by the accommodative stance of monetary policy and, more recently, by declines in longer-term interest rates as the prospects for credible federal deficit cuts improved. From the time monetary policy began to move toward ease in 1989 until now, short-term interest rates have dropped more than two-thirds and long-term rates have also declined substantially. All along the maturity spectrum, interest rates have come down to their lowest levels in twenty or thirty years, aiding the repair of balance sheets, bolstering the cash flow of borrowers, and providing support for interest-sensitive spending.

The process of easing monetary policy, however, had to be closely controlled, and generally gradual, because of the constraint imposed by the marketplace's acute sensitivity to inflation. As I pointed out in my February testimony to the Congress, this constraint did not exist in earlier years. Before the late 1970s, financial market participants and others apparently believed that although inflationary pressures might surface occasionally, the institutional structure of the U.S. economy simply would not permit sustained inflation. But as inflation and, consequently, long-term interest rates soared into the double digits at the end of the 1970s, investors became painfully aware that they had underestimated the economy's potential for inflation. As a result, monetary policy in recent years has had to remain alert to the possibility that an ill-timed easing could be undone by a flare-up of inflation expectations, pushing long-term interest rates higher and short-circuiting essential balance sheet repair.

The cumulative monetary easing over the past four years has been very substantial. Since last September, however, no further steps have been taken, as the stance of policy has appeared broadly appropriate to the evolving economic circumstances.

That stance has been quite accommodative, especially judging by the level of real short-term interest rates in the context of moderate economic growth, on average. Short-term real interest rates have been about zero over the past three quarters. In maintaining this accommodative stance, we have been persuaded by evidence of persistent slack in labor and product markets, increasing international competitiveness, and a decided absence of excessive credit and money expansion. The forces that engendered past inflationary episodes appear to have been lacking to date.

Yet some of the readings on inflation earlier this year were disturbing. It appeared that prices might be accelerating despite product market slack and an unemployment rate that was noticeably above estimates of the so-called "natural" rate of unemployment--that is, the rate at which price pressures remain roughly constant. In the past, the existing degree of slack in the economy had been consistent with continuing disinflation.

History tells us, however, the inflation outcome depends not only on the amount of slack remaining in labor and product markets but on other factors as well, including the rate at which that slack is changing. If the economy is growing rapidly, inflation pressures can arise, even in the face of excess capacity, as temporary bottle-necks emerge and as workers and producers raise wages and prices in anticipation of continued strengthening in demand. Near the end of last year, about the time many firms probably were finalizing their plans for 1993, sales and capacity utilization were moving up markedly and optimism about future economic activity surged. This optimism may well have set in motion a wave of price increases, which showed through to broad measures of prices earlier this year.

Moreover, inflation expectations, at least by some measures, appear to have tilted upward this year, possibly contributing to price pressures. The University of Michigan survey of consumer attitudes, for example, reported an increase in the inflation rate that is expected to prevail over the next twelve months from about 3 3/4 percent in the fourth quarter of last year to nearly 4 1/2 percent in the second quarter. Preliminary data imply some easing of such expectations earlier this month, but the sample from which those data are derived is too small to be persuasive. Moreover, the price of gold, which can broadly reflect inflationary expectations, has risen sharply in recent months. And at times this spring, bond yields spiked higher when incoming news about inflation was most discouraging.

The role of expectations in the inflation process is crucial. Even expectations not validated by economic fundamentals can themselves add appreciably to wage and price pressures for a considerable period, potentially derailing the economy from its growth track.

Why, for example, despite an above-normal rate of unemployment and permanent layoffs, have uncertainties about job security not led to further moderation in wage increases? The answer appears to lie, at least in part, in the deep-seated anticipations understandably harbored by workers that inflation is likely to reaccelerate in the near term and undercut their real wages.

The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) became concerned that inflation expectations and price pressures, unless contained, could raise long-term interest rates and stall economic expansion. Consequently, at its meeting in May, while affirming the more accommodative policy stance in place since last September, the FOMC also deemed it appropriate to initiate a so-called asymmetric directive. With its bias in the direction of a possible firming of policy over the intermeeting period, this directive did not prejudge that action would be taken--and indeed none was taken. But it did indicate that further signs of a potential deterioration of the inflation outlook would merit serious consideration as to whether short-term rates needed to be raised slightly from their relatively low levels to ensure that financial conditions remained conducive to sustained growth.

Certainly the May and June price figures have helped assuage concerns that new inflationary pressures had taken hold. Nonetheless, on balance, the news on inflation this year must be characterized as disappointing. Despite disinflationary forces and continued slack, the rate of inflation has at best stabilized, rather than easing further as past relationships would have suggested.

In assessing the stance of monetary policy and the likelihood of persistent inflationary pressures, the FOMC took into account the down-shift in the pace of economic expansion earlier this year. This down-shift left considerable remaining slack in the economy and promised that the adverse price movements prompted by the acceleration in growth late last year would likely diminish.

Although a slowdown from the unsustainable rapid growth in the latter part of last year had been anticipated, the deceleration was greater than expected. A surprisingly precipitous drop in defense spending, a sharp deterioration in net exports, a major blizzard, and some inevitable retrenchment by consumers converged to yield only meager gains in output in the first quarter. But growth apparently picked up in the second quarter, and nearly one million net new jobs were created over the first half of the year. Smoothing through the quarterly pattern, the economy appears to have accelerated gradually over the past two years, to maintain a pace of growth that should yield further reductions in the unemployment rate. Consequently, the evidence remains consistent with our diagnosis that the underlying forces at work are keeping the economy generally on a moderate upward track. However, as I have often emphasized, not all the old economic and financial verities have held in the current expansion, and changes in fiscal policy will have uncertain effects in the future. Thus, caution remains appropriate in assessing the path for the economy.

Financial conditions have improved considerably, lessening the need for balance sheet restructuring that has been damping economic activity for several years, By no means is the process over, but good progress has been made. On the one hand, debt service burdens, eased by lower interest rates and lower debt-equity ratios, have fallen substantially in both the business and household sectors. On the other hand, the economies of several of our major trading partners have been quite weak, constraining the growth of demand for our exports.

Although expectations of a significant, credible decline in the budget deficit have induced lower long-term interest rates and favorably affected the economy, the positive influence thus far is apparently being at least partly offset by some business spending reductions as a consequence of concerns about the effects of pending tax increases.

It seems that the prospective cuts in the deficit are having a variety of substantial economic effects, well in advance of any actual change in taxes or in projected outlays. Moreover, uncertainty about the final shape of the package may itself be injecting a note of caution into private spending plans. In addition, uncertainty about the outlook for health care reform may be affecting spending at least in that industry.

To be sure, the conventional wisdom is that budget deficit reduction restrains economic growth for a time, and I suspect that is probably correct. However, over the long run, conventional wisdom points in the opposite direction. In fact, one can infer that recent declines in long-term interest rates are bringing forward some of these anticipated long-term gains. As a consequence, the timing and magnitude of any net restraint from deficit reduction are uncertain. Patently, the overall economic effect of fiscal policy, especially when combined with the uncertainties of the forthcoming health care reform package, has imparted several unconventional unknowns to the economic outlook.

However, assuming that we constructively resolve over time the major questions about federal budget and health care policies, with further waning of earlier restraints on growth the U.S. economy should eventually emerge healthier and more vibrant than in decades. The balance sheet restructuring of both financial and nonfinancial establishments in recent years should leave the various sectors of the economy in much better shape and better able to weather untoward developments. Similarly, the ongoing efforts by corporations to pare expenses are putting our firms and our industries in a better position to compete both within the U.S. market and globally. And after a period of some dislocation the contraction in the defense sector will ultimately mean a freeing-up of resources for more productive uses. Finally, a credible and effective fiscal package would promise an improved outlook for sustained lower long-term interest rates and a better environment for private sector investment, All told, the productive capacity of the economy will doubtless be higher and its resilience greater.

Over the past two years, the forces of restraint on the economy have changed, but real growth has continued, with one sector of the economy after another taking the lead. Against this background, Federal Reserve Board governors and Reserve Bank presidents project that the U.S. economy will remain on the moderate growth path it has been following as the expansion has progressed. Their forecasts for real GDP average about 2 1/2 percent from the fourth quarter of 1992 to the fourth quarter of 1993 and cluster around 2 1/2 percent to 3 1/4 percent over the four quarters of 1994. Reflecting this moderate rise and the outlook for labor productivity, unemployment is generally expected to edge lower, to about 63/4 percent by the end of this year and to perhaps a shade lower by the end of next year. For this year as a whole, FOMC participants see inflation at or just above 3 percent, and most of them have about the same forecast for next year.

Besides focusing on the outlook for the economy at its July meeting, the FOMC, as required by the Humphrey-Hawkins Act, set ranges for the growth of money and debt for this year and, on a preliminary basis, for 1994. One premise of the discussion of the ranges was that the uncharacteristically slow growth of the broad monetary aggregates in the past couple years--and the atypical increases in their velocities--would persist for a while longer. M2 has been far weaker than income and interest rates would have predicted. Indeed, if the historical relationships between M2 and nominal income had remained intact, the behavior of M2 in recent years would have been consistent with that of an economy in severe contraction. To an important degree, the behavior of M2 has reflected structural changes in the financial sector: The thrift industry has downsized by necessity, and commercial banks have pulled back as well, largely reflecting the burgeoning loan losses that followed the lax lending of earlier years. With depository credit weak, there has been little bidding for deposits, and depositors in any case have been drawn to the higher returns on capital market instruments. Inflows to bond and stock mutual funds have reached record levels, and, to the extent that these inflows have come at the expense of growth in deposits or money market mutual funds, the broad monetary aggregates have been depressed.

In this context, the FOMC lowered the 1993 ranges for M2 and M3--to 1 percent to 5 percent and 0 percent to 4 percent respectively. This lowering represents a reduction of 1 percentage point in the M2 range and 1/2 percentage point for M3. Even with these reductions, we would not be surprised to see the monetary aggregates finish the year near the lower ends of their ranges.

As I emphasized in a similar context in February, the lowering of the ranges is purely a technical matter; it does not indicate, nor should it be perceived as, a shift of monetary policy toward restraint. It is indicative merely of (1) the state of our knowledge about the factors depressing the growth of the aggregates relative to spending, (2) the course of the aggregates to date, and (3) the likelihood of various outcomes through the end of the year. Although the lowering of the range reflects our judgment that shifts out of M2 will persist, the upper end of the revised range allows for a resumption of more normal behavior or even some unwinding of M2 shortfalls. The FOMC also lowered the 1993 range for debt of the domestic nonfinancial sectors 1/2 percentage point, to 4 percent to 8 percent. The debt aggregate is likely to come in comfortably within its new range, as it continues growing about in line with nominal GDP. The new ranges for growth of money and debt in 1993 were carried over on a preliminary basis into 1994.

In reading the longer-run intentions of the FOMC, one should interpret the specific ranges cautiously. The historical relationships between money and income and between money and the price level have largely broken down, depriving the aggregates of much of their usefulness as guides to policy. At least for the time being, M2 has been downgraded as a reliable indicator of financial conditions in the economy, and no single variable has yet been identified to take its place.

At one time, M2 was useful both to guide Federal Reserve policy and to communicate the thrust of monetary policy to others, Even then, however, a wide range of data was routinely evaluated to assure ourselves that M2 was capturing the important elements in the financial system that would affect the economy. The FOMC never single-mindedly adhered to a narrow path for M2, but persistent and sizable deviations of that aggregate from expectations were a warning sign that policy and the economy might not be interacting in a way that would produce the desired results. The so-called "P-star" model, developed in the late 1980s, embodied a long-run relationship between M2 and prices that could anchor policy over extended periods of time. But that long-run relationship also seems to have broken down with the persistent rise in M2 velocity.

M2 and P-star may reemerge as reliable indicators of income and prices once (1) the yield curve has returned to a more normal configuration, (2) borrowers' balance sheets have been restored and traditional credit demands resume, (3) savers have adjusted to the enhanced availability of alternative investments, and (4) depositories finally have reached a comfortable size relative to their capital and earnings. In the meantime, the process of probing a variety of data to ascertain underlying economic and financial conditions has become even more essential to formulating sound monetary policy. This general approach obviously has its weaknesses. When one examines many indicators, one can always find some that counsel against actions that later appear to have been necessary.

In these circumstances, it is especially prudent to focus on longer-term policy guides. One important guidepost is real interest rates, which have a key bearing on longer-run spending decisions and inflation prospects.

In assessing real rates, the central issue is their relationship to an equilibrium interest rate, specifically the real rate level that, if maintained, would keep the economy at its production potential over time. Rates persisting above that level, history tells us, tend to be associated with slack, disinflation, and economic stagnation, and rates below that level tend to be associated with eventual resource bottlenecks and rising inflation, which ultimately engender economic contraction. Maintaining the real rate around its equilibrium level should have a stabilizing effect on the economy, directing production toward its long-term potential.

The level of the equilibrium real rate--or more appropriately the equilibrium term structure of real rates--cannot be estimated with a great deal of confidence, though it can be estimated with enough confidence to be useful for monetary policy. Real rates, of course, are not directly observable but must be inferred from nominal interest rates and estimates of inflation expectations. The most important real rates for private spending decisions almost surely are the longer maturities. Moreover, the equilibrium rate structure responds to the ebb and flow of underlying forces affecting spending. So, for example, in recent years the appropriate real rate structure doubtless has been depressed by the headwinds of balance sheet restructuring and fiscal retrenchment. Despite the uncertainties about the levels of equilibrium and actual real interest rates, rough judgments about these variables can be made and used in conjunction with other indicators in the monetary policy process. Currently, short-term real rates, most directly affected by the Federal Reserve, are not far from zero; long-term rates, set primarily by the market, are appreciably higher, judging from the steep slope of the yield curve and reasonable suppositions about inflation expectations. This configuration indicates that market participants anticipate that short-term real rates will have to rise as the headwinds diminish if substantial inflationary imbalances are to be avoided.

Although our guides for policy may have changed recently, our goals have not. As I have indicated many times to this committee, the Federal Reserve seeks to foster maximum sustainable economic growth and rising standards of living. And in that endeavor, the most productive function the central bank can perform is to achieve and maintain price stability.

Inflation is counterproductive in many ways. Of particular importance, increased inflation has been found to be associated with reduced growth of productivity, apparently in part because it confounds relative price movements and obscures price signals. Compounding this negative effect, under the current tax code, inflation raises the effective taxation of savings and investment, discouraging the process of capital formation. Because productivity growth is the only source of lasting increases in real incomes and because even small changes in growth rates of productivity can accumulate over time to large differences in living standards, productivity growth's association with inflation is of key importance to policymakers.

The link between the control of inflation and the growth of productivity underscores the importance of providing a stable backdrop for the economy. Such an environment is especially important for an increasingly dynamic market economy, such as ours, in which technology and telecommunications are advancing rapidly. New firms, new products, new jobs, new industries, and new markets are continually being created, and they are unceremoniously displacing the old ones. The U.S. economy is a dynamic system that is always renewing itself. It is extraordinary that the system overall is as stable as it is, considering the persistent process of change in the structure of our economy. For example, a frequently cited figure is the two million new jobs that have been created since the end of 1991. This is a net change, however, which masks the many millions of people who found, lost, and changed jobs over the same period. Currently, people are being hired at a pace of approximately 400,000 per week, while job losses are running modestly below that figure. Such vast churning in the nation's labor markets is a normal and ultimately a productive process.

Central planning of the type that prevailed in postwar Eastern Europe and the Soviet Union represented one attempt to fashion an economic system that eliminated this competitive churning and its presumed wastefulness. But when that system eliminated the risk of failure, it also stifled the incentive to innovate and to prosper. Central planning fostered stasis: In many respects, the eastern bloc economies marched in place for more than four decades.

Risk-taking is crucial in the process that leads to a vital and progressive economy. Indeed, it is a necessary condition for wealth creation. In a market economy, competition and innovation interact; those firms that are slow to innovate or to anticipate the demands of the consumer are soon left behind. The pace of churning differs by industry, but it is present in all. At one extreme, firms in the most high tech areas must remain constantly on the cutting edge, as products and knowledge rapidly become obsolete. Many products that were at technology's leading edge, say five years ago, are virtually unsalable in today's markets. In high tech fields, leadership can shift rapidly. In some markets in which American firms were losing share just a few years ago, we have regained considerable dominance. In one case, U.S. firms have seized a commanding lead in just two years in the new laptop computer market, and now these firms account for more than 60 percent of U.S. sales last year, triple the figure for Japanese firms.

More generally, it appears that the pace of dynamism has been accelerating. One indication is that the average economic life expectancy of new capital equipment has been falling. The average life of equipment purchased in 1982, for example, was 16 1/2 years. By 1992 that figure had declined to 14 1/2 years, a decline more than twice as large as that over the preceding decade. In addition, telecommunications technology is obviously quickening the decisionmaking process in both financial and product markets.

In such a rapidly changing marketplace, the agile survive by being flexible. One aspect of this flexibility has been the spread of "just-in-time" inventory controls at manufacturing firms. Partly as a result of innovations in inventory control techniques, the variability of inventories relative to total output appears to be on a downtrend.

The possibility of failure has productive side effects, encouraging economic agents to do their best to succeed. But there are nonproductive and unnecessary risks as well. There is no way to avoid risk altogether, given the inherently uncertain outcomes of all business and household decisions. But many uncertainties and risks do not foster economic progress, and when feasible should be suppressed. A crucial risk in this category is that induced by inflation. To allow a market economy to attain its potential, the unnecessary instability engendered by inflation must be quieted.

A monetary policy that aims at price stability permits low long-term interest rates and helps provide a stable setting to foster the investment and innovation by the private sector that are key to long-run economic growth. In pursuing our objectives, we must remain acutely aware that the structure of the economy has been changing and growing ever more complex. The relationships between the key variables in the economy are always shifting to a degree, and this evolution presents an ongoing challenge to the business leader, to the econometric modeler, and to those responsible for the conduct of economic policy.

Clearly, the behavior of many of the forces acting on the economy over the course of the last business cycle has been different from what had gone before. The sensitivity of inflation expectations has been heightened, and, as recent evidence suggests, businesses and households may be becoming more forward-looking with respect to fiscal policies as well.

I believe we are on our way toward reestablishing the trust in the purchasing power of the dollar that is crucial to maximizing and fulfilling the productive capacity of this nation. However, the public clearly remains to be convinced. Survey responses and financial market prices embody expectations that the current lower level of inflation not only will not be bettered, but it will not even persist. But there are glimmers of hope that trust is reemerging. For example, issuers have found receptive markets in recent months for fifty-year bonds. This had not happened in decades. The reopening of that market may be read as one indication that some investors once again believe that inflationary pressures will remain subdued.

It is my firm belief that, with fiscal consolidation and with the monetary policy path that we have charted, the United States is well positioned to remain at the forefront of the world economy well into the next century. (1.) See "Monetary Policy Report to the Congress," in this issue.
COPYRIGHT 1993 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 1993, Gale Group. All rights reserved. Gale Group is a Thomson Corporation Company.

Article Details
Printer friendly Cite/link Email Feedback
Title Annotation:remarks about Federal Reserve Board's semiannual monetary policy report dated July 1993
Author:Greenspan, Alan
Publication:Federal Reserve Bulletin
Article Type:Transcript
Date:Sep 1, 1993
Words:4447
Previous Article:Industrial production and capacity utilization for June 1993.
Next Article:Minutes of the Federal Open Market Committee meeting of May 18, 1993.
Topics:


Related Articles
Statement to the Congress.
Minutes of the Federal Open Market Committee Meeting of March 23, 1993.
Minutes of the Federal Open Market Committee meeting of May 18, 1993.
Record of policy actions of the Federal Open Market Committee.
Statement by Alan Greenspan, Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs,...
Statement by Alan Greenspan, Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, before the Committee on the Budget, U.S. House of...
Statement by Alan Greenspan, Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, before the Subcommittee on Economic Growth and Credit...
Minutes of the Federal Open Market Committee meeting of December 21, 1993.
Minutes of the Federal Open Market Committee meeting held on January 31-February 1, 1995.
Statements to Congress.

Terms of use | Copyright © 2016 Farlex, Inc. | Feedback | For webmasters