Printer Friendly
The Free Library
22,728,043 articles and books

Public-private partnerships in Canada: theory and evidence.



This article examines the emerging issues regarding the implementation and performance of public-private partnerships (P3s) in Canada, focusing primarily on infrastructure projects. A number of projects with P3 characteristics began to emerge across Canada Across Canada was an afternoon program that formerly aired on The Weather Network. The segment ran from early 1999 until mid 2002. The show ran from 3:00PM ET until 7:00 PM ET.  in the 1980s, but it was not until the mid-1990s that P3s really began to take hold. From a public policy perspective, there are three important questions for potential initiating governments: 1) What goals do they expect to achieve through the use of P3s? 2) How effective have implemented P3s been at delivering value to governments and citizens? 3) Are there lessons that can be learned and, more importantly, generalized? These questions are important for Canadian policy because emerging evidence from a number of countries suggests considerable dissatisfaction with the outcomes of many P3s. These countries include the United Kingdom, (1) Ireland, (2) the Netherlands, (3) Denmark (4) and Australia. (5)

The article first reviews posited government rationales for P3s. Second, we propose a "positive theory" perspective on P3s that attempts to explain actual P3 behaviour and outcomes. This perspective is based on an eclectic mix of public choice theory, transaction cost economics, and past experience with contracting-out government services, "mixed" enterprises and P3s. Third, we review and evaluate ten Canadian P3s in light of this positive theory perspective. Finally, we synthesize To create a whole or complete unit from parts or components. See synthesis.  and summarize this evidence.

Although risk transfer is a major posited goal of many public-sector governments, at least initially, our review of the Canadian evidence suggests that, in negotiating (and re-negotiating) P3s, government has often failed to achieve significant risk transfer, especially that which is related to use-risk. Use-risk is usually, but not always, equivalent to revenue risk. Additionally, we find that the transaction costs of many P3s appear to be high. These transaction costs include ex ante contracting and negotiation costs, as well as ex post (i.e., after formal contract agreement) costs, such as monitoring, renegotiation and termination costs. These costs may be borne by government, by the private sector, or both. But, no matter by whom these costs are borne, they represent real social costs that must be considered in assessing the benefits of P3s.

The case-study findings on which we report are generally consistent with the positive theory perspective outlined below. They suggest that Canadian governments have sometimes found it difficult to effectively reduce either their total costs (that is, the sum of production and transaction costs) or their budgetary risk exposure (by transferring revenue risk) through the use of P3s. At the same time, the for-profit, private-sector partners have sometimes had difficulty generating adequate profitability, although this is a tentative conclusion, since they have usually had incentives to publicly emphasize losses, or potential losses, and to be secretive about profits. One surprising occurrence is the dissolution of the P3 more quickly than envisioned in the original contract, through government buy-outs, re-design of the contract, bankruptcy of the private entity, or some mix of these. A more common outcome, however, is protracted pro·tract  
tr.v. pro·tract·ed, pro·tract·ing, pro·tracts
1. To draw out or lengthen in time; prolong: disputants who needlessly protracted the negotiations.

2.
 conflict, with high contracting costs borne by one party, or both.

Our findings throw into doubt the social desirability of P3s as a widely replicable mechanism for delivering public infrastructure. More encouragingly, however, P3s in Canada have worked reasonably in certain specific circumstances, namely, where 1) governments have not attempted to transfer use-risk or revenue risk to the private sector; 2) projects have required specialized knowledge or proprietary technology that is only held by private-sector firms (usually a small number of large global firms); and 3) governments were able to transfer construction risk at something close to a fixed price. These circumstances are close to traditional "design-build-transfer" or "build-transfer" contracts. Government must either recognize that P3s should be limited to projects that meet these conditions or they must do much better at reducing the potential for high transaction costs in contract design. Ideally, this means writing contracts that bind their own future behaviour as well as that of private-sector participants.

Government rationales for P3s

There has been a long history of public subsidies for large-scale, private-sector infrastructure in Canada; railroads are one example of this subsidization sub·si·dize  
tr.v. sub·si·dized, sub·si·diz·ing, sub·si·diz·es
1. To assist or support with a subsidy.

2. To secure the assistance of by granting a subsidy.
. (6) Close linkages between the public and private sectors reemerged in Canada in the mid-1990s in the form of P3s. Canadian governments, like those in Europe and Australia, have been most attracted to P3s in capital-intensive areas, which can loosely be labelled as infrastructure, especially in transportation and in water and wastewater treatment.

Governments have articulated three major rationales for engaging in P3s. (7) The first rationale is the minimization of on-budget government expenditures and/or the desire not to increase current debt levels. The second derives from the private sector's ability to provide both infrastructure and services at lower cost due to economies of scale, more experience, better incentives and greater ability to innovate. The third rationale relates to the government's desire to reduce risk, especially during the design and construction phase, but also during the operating phase.

Concerning the first rationale for P3s--eliminating up-front capital expenditures and keeping capital projects off current government balance sheets--there are often political benefits from keeping capital expenditures off the government's official budget. (8) However, it is important to emphasize that the underlying economic reality of the investment is not altered if it is not on the books. No matter how a project is financed, the government (or users) ultimately have to pay for its construction and operation. (9) By using a P3, government can spread its cost obligations over a longer time-period. As this mainly affects the timing of the payments and is not likely to reduce costs, the normative basis of this rationale is weak. In some cases, though, time-shifting can be justified on legitimate inter-generational efficiency and distributional grounds. It is most justifiable for long-lived infrastructure projects that provide benefits over a number of generational cohorts. The need to use P3s for this purpose may also represent the presence of institutional barriers within governments that result in an unwillingness or inability to create adequate capital financing mechanisms. (10) The situation in Canada can be contrasted with that in the U.S., where there is a well-developed municipal bond market. (11) However, these versions of the financing advantage argument are rarely articulated in detail. Rather, it appears that governments have a desire to provide services but not have the costs show up in the budget. This is consistent with a public choice interpretation for the adoption of P3s: current politicians can provide voters with the benefits of projects but can defer the costs to future politicians and/or future (myopic my·o·pi·a  
n.
1. A visual defect in which distant objects appear blurred because their images are focused in front of the retina rather than on it; nearsightedness. Also called short sight.

2.
) users. It does not provide a fundamental normative economic rationale for the adoption of P3s.

The second rationale for P3s is that such partnering can provide both infrastructure and services at lower cost. There are a number of strands to this cost-superiority argument. The major argument is that private-sector firms have superior scale, scope or learning economies because they are more specialized, larger and have more experience in the construction and operation of the relevant businesses. Indeed, private-sector infrastructure firms may be global in scope. In contrast, governments engage in much more diverse activities and usually have less specific expertise or experience with the relevant technology or activity. This cost difference is likely to be especially applicable to smaller provincial, regional and municipal governments. Any such cost advantages are likely to be most substantial for design and construction. Another cost-superiority argument is that the private sector has superior incentives to minimize costs and, as a result, to squeeze out and lower potential agency costs Agency Costs

The costs resulting from an agent performing services for a principal.

Notes:
Agency costs are generally the commissions earned by agents.
See also: Agency Problem, Agent, Principal



Agency costs
. (12) Because of cost-reduction incentives, the private sector may have more cost-efficient operations, such as procurement policies, and better project management skills, holding scale constant. These superior incentives are likely to become most evident in the dynamic aspects of projects; for example, in a greater willingness to alter project specifications or to utilize new technologies to reduce costs. (13) Also, the private sector may also have lower wage costs, possibly due to hiring non-union labour. (14) A final strand of this argument that focuses on the public sector is that monopoly public-sector bureaucracies are particularly prone to technical or X-inefficiency.

Many would argue that technical efficiency considerations are the normatively best argument for P3s. It makes sense on a priori a priori

In epistemology, knowledge that is independent of all particular experiences, as opposed to a posteriori (or empirical) knowledge, which derives from experience.
 grounds, and there is considerable evidence from a wide variety of jurisdictions that large government-produced infrastructure projects often cost far more than budgeted. (15) However, it is important to bear in mind that the first-order outcome of private-sector cost-superiority is higher private-sector returns rather than lower public-sector costs.

A third rationale is that, through the use of P3s, the public sector can reduce the risk associated with its financial exposure to construction costs, maintenance costs and usage levels (revenue). The private-sector partner often engages in similar projects simultaneously and can, therefore, spread the risk of a particular project among a number of similar projects, although governments may have more ability to spread risks over a larger number of projects in total. (16) Either way, however, this is not a strong normative justification for P3s, since it does not reduce risk per se; it only transfers and spreads risk more broadly. The private sector may also be able to price risk more effectively and thereby lower it. Usually, the private sector does have (or can more easily access) more expertise with sophisticated financial instruments and better access to markets that can allocate risks to parties most able to price and bear it efficiently. And, finally, of course, the private sector is less susceptible to political risk, although this can affect them adversely. The U.K. government has been a leader in arguing that the various dimensions of risk transfer should be the primary goal of P3s--usually called "private finance initiatives" (PFIs) in the U.K. (17) From a normative perspective, the key question is this: at what price?

Governments have variously articulated all three of these rationales for engaging in P3s, especially the first and third rationales. All three, whether correct or not, have at least some patina of normative justification. The second rationale is clearly the strongest, since it is backed by extensive empirical evidence of governments' underestimating project costs. The major problem with it from a normative perspective is that the argument is incomplete in two respects. First, Oliver Williamson and others have emphasized that such a criterion ignores transaction costs. (18) Transaction costs include the cost of negotiating, monitoring and, if necessary, re-negotiating contracts with private-sector partners, both ex ante (prior to the award of a contract) and ex post (after the contract has been let). In practice, these project costs are usually excluded from the project budget, although they are often captured in other government budgets, for example, in government legal and procurement departments. Williamson implies that governments should minimize the sum of production costs and transaction costs. Second, however, even this broader criterion excludes non-governmental social costs, some of which should obviously be included in a comprehensive social accounting. Steven Globerman and Aidan Vining suggest that ultimately the effectiveness and desirability of P3s and related instruments depend on their ability to meet the needs of society as a whole, that is, whether the net social benefits of P3s are likely to be higher (or are actually higher) than government provision. (19) This criterion has a strong normative rationale and has been used to evaluate the privatization privatization: see nationalization.
privatization

Transfer of government services or assets to the private sector. State-owned assets may be sold to private owners, or statutory restrictions on competition between privately and publicly owned
 of state-owned enterprises. (20) One drawback of this criterion for some will be that it treats payments to private-sector partners as a transfer: the net social benefits of a project are unchanged even if a government over-pays for a project. Following Williamson, but recognizing the importance of externalities externalities

side-effects, either harmful or beneficial, borne by those not directly involved in the production of a commodity.
 and quality differences, Anthony Boardman and Erica Hewitt argue that governments should minimize the sum of total social costs defined as production costs incurred by government or paid to third parties, plus transaction costs, plus (net) negative externalities, holding quality constant. (21) We argue here that this criterion is the most appropriate normative criterion by which to judge the efficacy of P3s.

A fourth rationale, which is usually not articulated, is that governments believe (or at least want to believe) that private-sector operation makes it politically more feasible to impose user-fees, resulting in lower net expenditures for government. The reasoning is that users (and voters) are more willing to accept that the private sector needs revenue to cover its costs, repay its debt or make a profit than the argument that the public sector needs to do so. Even this rationale has some normative justification when there are positive marginal social costs from public use, for example, where highways are tolled to reduce overuse overuse Health care The common use of a particular intervention even when the benefits of the intervention don't justify the potential harm or cost–eg, prescribing antibiotics for a probable viral URI. Cf Misuse, Underuse. .

A number of critics of P3s argue that the potential cost-efficiency advantages of P3s are offset by the fact that financing costs will generally be lower for the public sector. On their face, government bonds generally carry a lower interest rate than corporate bonds. Also, governments may have more ability to spread risk over a larger number of projects. However, Jean-Etienne de Bettignies and Thomas Ross convincingly argue that governments are generally not able to borrow at a lower cost than the private sector. (22) Furthermore, some governments are now providing equivalent tax-exempt status to P3s, further levelling the playing field on the financing dimension (from a social efficiency perspective, of course, taxes are primarily transfers).

A positive theory perspective: incorporating partners' objectives and transaction costs

This section sketches a positive theory perspective that attempts to throw light on both the adoption and evaluation of P3s: "The primary concern of [positive] perspectives is ... explanation and prediction, not ... evaluation and improvement." (23) It is presented as a "perspective" rather than a fully articulated theory because our purpose is narrower than a full theory. We draw on positive theory to explain at least some aspects of P3 outcomes that normative theory does not. However, it is important to emphasize that this positive perspective is not necessarily antithetical an·ti·thet·i·cal   also an·ti·thet·ic
adj.
1. Of, relating to, or marked by antithesis.

2. Being in diametrical opposition. See Synonyms at opposite.
 to normative theory (therefore the use of the word "primarily"). We follow Joseph Cordes, who argues that a "good case can be made that the normative and positive traditions are best viewed as complements rather than substitutes to each other in the evaluation ... of a variety of public policies." (24)

Above, we argued that, normatively, governments should seek to minimize the sum of total social costs: namely, production costs plus transaction costs plus (net) negative externalities, holding quality constant. In assessing the expected costs and benefits of P3s versus government production or standard contracting, one must include transaction costs and externalities. We argue that to assess the sum of these costs, it is essential to consider the goals of the "partners" in a P3.

While the language of partnership is endemic to P3s, our premise is that the public and private participants have conflicting goals (25) and that this divergence is likely to raise transaction costs and externalities. Studies have shown that in other inter-organizational contexts with conflicting goals the result is high contract bargaining costs, opportunistic behaviour by one or both sides, failure to achieve goals, and partnership dissolution. For example, firms that are jointly owned by private shareholders and government can lead to "the worst of both worlds," achieving neither high profitability nor worthwhile social goals. (26) Contracting-out by government is also prone to the risk of hold-up and high bargaining costs. (27) Even private-sector joint ventures, where both partners have profit goals, also experience high conflict, extensive opportunism Opportunism
Arabella, Lady

squire’s wife matchmakes with money in mind. [Br. Lit.: Doctor Thorne]

Ashkenazi, Simcha

shrewdly and unscrupulously becomes merchant prince. [Yiddish Lit.
 and high failure rates. (28)

Private-sector participants wish to maximize risk-adjusted profits over the contract life. The public sector wishes to minimize the sum of the current government's expected short-term expenditures, on-the-budget expenditures and political costs. The details in these objective functions are important, because they foreshadow fore·shad·ow  
tr.v. fore·shad·owed, fore·shad·ow·ing, fore·shad·ows
To present an indication or a suggestion of beforehand; presage.



fore·shad
 the reasons for conflict and high transaction costs, both before and after, contract agreement in P3s. We now consider each objective function in more detail.

Private-sector objective function

Private-sector participants wish to maximize profits over the contract life. The point we emphasize here is that profit maximization In economics, profit maximization is the process by which a firm determines the price and output level that returns the greatest profit. There are several approaches to this problem.  is not a one-period phenomenon: if private-sector actors find new profit opportunities as the contract unfolds, they will seek to capture them. Of course, if contracts are written very tightly, they will have little opportunity to do so. However, there is usually some scope to engage in this form of behaviour, or opportunism. (The evidence certainly suggests that governments often perceive many contract renegotiation efforts as opportunistic.) It seems to be a particular problem if the private-sector partner changes ownership, perhaps because new owners are less bound by tacit "understandings."

Additionally, private-sector participants are risk-adjusted profit maximizers: they are willing to forego some expected profits if they can reduce risk sufficiently. Indeed, private-sector participants may be considerably more risk-averse than public-sector participants, at least ex ante. One reason is that private-sector actors typically bear the consequences more directly and personally of taking risks that turn out badly. As a result, the private-sector participants require high premiums to accept risk, especially the various dimensions of use-risk (also often called revenue or demand risk). Many private partners are relatively unfamiliar with the particular use-risks associated with government projects. This is less true with global firms that specialize in P3-type projects. But, as a corollary corollary: see theorem. , these firms are more aware that they often have little control over many of the factors that drive demand. For example, if they construct and operate atoll atoll: see coral reefs.
atoll

Coral reef enclosing a lagoon. Atolls consist of ribbons of reef that may not be circular but that are closed shapes, sometimes miles across, around a lagoon that may be 160 ft (50 m) deep or more.
 highway, they know they will have little influence over regional transportation policy that might dramatically affect their toll revenues. Furthermore, use-risk is almost always potentially subject to ex post manipulation by the political partners. Of course, the private sector will formally accept use-risk if the premium is high enough, just as we can get a fixed-price contract for our house renovation if we are prepared to pay a high enough price. In the end, though, this price is usually so high that we opt for the variable labour-and-materials contract, where the price is not fixed. In order to minimize their risk generally, even when use-risk has been avoided, sophisticated private-sector partners are likely to 1) form stand-alone P3 corporations, (29) thereby reducing their worst-case costs by declaring the stand-alone corporation bankrupt, if necessary, and/or 2) limit their capital exposure through the utilization of extensive third-party debt-financing. (30)

Finally, the likelihood that P3s will deliver projects at lower production cost depends on a private-sector partner having the appropriate incentives to equate their profit maximization with project cost minimization. If, for example, firms are de facto [Latin, In fact.] In fact, in deed, actually.

This phrase is used to characterize an officer, a government, a past action, or a state of affairs that must be accepted for all practical purposes, but is illegal or illegitimate.
 remunerated re·mu·ner·ate  
tr.v. re·mu·ner·at·ed, re·mu·ner·at·ing, re·mu·ner·ates
1. To pay (a person) a suitable equivalent in return for goods provided, services rendered, or losses incurred; recompense.

2.
 on a "cost-plus" basis because of poorly written contracts, they will have an incentive to increase, rather than lower, project costs. (31) Similarly, if firms form stand-alone corporations or limit their equity participation, as suggested above, they may have opportunities to minimize losses (a form of profit maximization), even though this raises costs for government.

Public-sector objective function

To reiterate, the specific governmental objective function that we propose is to minimize the sum of current government expected short-term expenditures, on-the-books expenditures and political costs. This implies that governments are not as concerned with minimizing social costs (perhaps because they recognize the weakness of the argument that removing expenditures from the budget is a real cost-saving) as they are with the political benefits that result from the minimization of both present expenditures and on-budget expenditures. (32) This explicitly introduces a public choice overlay to transaction costs, (33) because, in general, vote-maximizing behaviour by politicians raises transaction costs and, therefore, aggregate social costs.

Governments normally prefer off-budget expenditures to on-budget expenditures, because voters receive infrastructure benefits, but are less likely to perceive the costs, a form of fiscal illusion. Furthermore, this objective function focuses on the goals of the current government. Holding all else constant, a current government prefers future expenditures that appear in future budgets (with potentially different politicians) to present expenditures. While we would argue that this is a fairly pervasive preference, current governments' discount rates do vary--a government that expects to stay in power over several electoral cycles will weight the cost of future expenditures more heavily. But, in sum, again holding everything else constant, a current government prefers infrastructure delivery mechanisms that involve future expenditures and off-budget expenditures.

When considering P3s, government must trade-off the political benefits that "future and off-budget" expenditures generate against other political costs and benefits. Other political costs could relate to eventual public dissatisfaction with subsequent private-sector "gouging Gouging can be:
  • The action of cutting or scooping with a gouge
  • Price gouging
  • Eye gouging or Fish-hooking in violent altercations or combat sports.
," poor service, high user-prices or whatever. The objective function focuses on the expected costs for the current government. The governments', especially politicians', expenditure-costs versus political-costs equation can change unpredictably. Indeed, political costs can shift from a weighting of "0" ex ante (i.e., before construction) to a weighting of "1" ex post (i.e., some period after construction completion, but before the expiration of the P3 contract). Additionally, future political costs do not have high saliency sa·li·ence   also sa·li·en·cy
n. pl. sa·li·en·ces also sa·li·en·cies
1. The quality or condition of being salient.

2. A pronounced feature or part; a highlight.

Noun 1.
 for current politicians. If they do arise, however, they have high saliency for the new cohort of politicians. When they arise, the private-sector participant may be able to "hold up" government and extract additional payments of various kinds because governments (especially elected politicians subject to voter discontent) often panic when faced with rising political costs. Rising user-fees most often provoke voter discontent.

The drivers of transaction costs in P3s

The fact that the goals of public and private participants are in conflict is not surprising. Still, if the potential gains from trade (i.e., "doing business") are sufficiently large In mathematics, the phrase sufficiently large is used in contexts such as:
is true for sufficiently large
, due, for example, to superior private-sector efficiency, P3s could produce "win-win" outcomes. However, a number of factors associated with infrastructure projects, especially larger projects that embody technological innovation (and therefore involve greater complexity and uncertainty), both reduce the likelihood that the public sector will achieve its goal and raise the transaction costs of utilizing the P3 format to deliver these projects.

Transaction costs in P3s are likely to be high because almost all infrastructure projects present relatively complex contracting situations. Indeed, one can think of P3s as simply government contracting-out, but under relatively unfavourable conditions. Transaction cost theory suggests that contracting costs are likely to be raised when projects exhibit high asset specificity Asset specificity is a term related to the inter-party relationships of a transaction. It has been extensively studied in a variety of management and economics areas such as marketing, accounting, organizational behavior and management information systems. , high complexity/uncertainty and low competitiveness. (34) Public-sector infrastructure--such as roads, hospitals and schools--usually involves considerable asset specificity. Most design work for a particular project is not usable for any other project and is, therefore, sunk (although knowledge and expertise that can be used elsewhere is not sunk). The value of infrastructure in other uses is very low and often negative.

There is some complexity/uncertainty in all P3 infrastructure projects because each is unique to some degree, if only in terms of topography. Many major projects are complex and may be unique on multiple dimensions. Uniqueness also raises the uncertainty around future usage and future willingness-to-pay for use. Finally, in circumstances where the project involves new or proprietary technology, there may be few alternative private-sector choices for construction, or even maintenance, so that competitiveness or even contestability is absent.

The difficulty in managing these potential transaction cost issues is greater if the government initiating the P3 has poor contract management skills. (35) Governments with weak contracting ability and experience will not have the skill to anticipate these contracting problems and write appropriate contract provisions for them before the contract is finalized.

Canadian P3 case studies

There has been a substantial increase in the use of P3s in Canada over the last decade. Table 1 provides basic information about the major P3s in Canada. It includes the term of the contracts, the dollar value of the contracts, and the public-sector and private-sector participants. It does not include projects that are effectively contacting-out (although the distinction is somewhat arbitrary).

Table 1 shows that P3s have been used for quite a few major infrastructure projects in Canada. These have been in many different areas, including transportation (roads, airports and bridges), water and wastewater, hospitals, recreation facilities, power and energy, and for other facilities. In addition to the projects listed above, P3s have been used to deliver many other smaller projects.

Independent studies of P3 performance are rare and admittedly difficult. However, we were able to review ten Canadian P3 projects in depth. Here, we update the three Canadian P3 cases examined previously by Anthony Boardman, Finn Poschmann and Aidan Vining (36) and add seven additional case studies, thereby providing a fairly broad range of empirical evidence. These studies were selected because of the availability of information, the size and profile of the projects, the jurisdictional coverage that they present, and the lessons they offer for P3 contract theory, design and implementation. The case studies examined are as follows: Alberta Special Waste Management System (Alberta), Confederation Bridge Confederation Bridge, Fr. Pont de la Confédération, bridge that joins Borden-Carleton in Prince Edward Island with Cape Jourimain in New Brunswick, Canada. Spanning the Northumberland Strait at its narrowest point, the bridge measures 8 mi (12.  (Federal), Highway 407 Express Toll Route (Ontario), Highway 104 Western Alignment Project (Nova Scotia), Evergreen Park School Evergreen Park School (also known as EPS), more commonly referred to as Evergreen Park or Evergreen, is an elementary-middle school in Moncton, New Brunswick, Canada. Currently, there are more than 900 students attending.  (New Brunswick New Brunswick, province, Canada
New Brunswick, province (2001 pop. 729,498), 28,345 sq mi (73,433 sq km), including 519 sq mi (1,345 sq km) of water surface, E Canada.
), O'Connell Drive Elementary School elementary school: see school.  (Nova Scotia), Britannia Mine Water Treatment Plant (British Columbia British Columbia, province (2001 pop. 3,907,738), 366,255 sq mi (948,600 sq km), including 6,976 sq mi (18,068 sq km) of water surface, W Canada. Geography
), Moncton Water Treatment Facility (New Brunswick), Cranbrook Civic Arena (British Columbia), and Waterloo Landfill Gas Power Plant (Ontario).

Alberta Special Waste Management System

The Alberta Special Waste Management System (ASWMS) was created in 1987 to build an integrated hazardous waste-treatment facility at Swan Hills, Alberta Swan Hills is a town (incorporated January 1, 1967) in northern Alberta, Canada. It is located  km ( mi) north of Whitecourt at the junction of Highway 32 and Grizzly Trail. Swan Hills is located in Municipal District of Big Lakes within census Division No. 17, Alberta. . It was forty-per-cent owned by a provincial Crown corporation and sixty per cent by a private firm (BOVAR Inc.). The private firm invested $30 million (sixty per cent of the plant's $50 million cost) and was to collect sixty per cent of the profits and all of the net earnings of the operator, Chem-Security. Under the agreement, BOVAR received a guaranteed minimum return on capital of three per cent over the current prime rate, depreciated Depreciated may refer to:
  • Depreciation, in finance, a reference to the fact that assets with finite lives lose value over time
  • Depreciated is often confused or used as a stand-in for "deprecated"; see deprecation for the use of depreciation in computer software
 at ten per cent per year for ten years, regardless of the profitability of the venture. (37) The province provided debt guarantees for BOVAR, as well as indemnity against future remediation or insurance liabilities in excess of $1 million. It also agreed to assume liability for clean up at Swan Hills, which was estimated at between $30 and $57 million. (38)

Alberta adopted a P3 because it believed that the private sector could build and operate the plant more efficiently than the public sector, although it recognized that the plant would not be commercially viable without subsidies. The parties later modified the agreement to permit a large capacity expansion. Partly as a result of this expansion, the subsidy turned out to be considerably larger than expected--approximately $445 million in total between 1986 and 1995. (39) However, the plant has operated at about only fifty per cent of its capacity through most of its life, and the additional capacity turned out to be excessive. In 1996, the Alberta government ended the joint venture by paying $140 million for full ownership of the facility. (40)

Currently, Swan Hills is the only integrated hazardous waste-management plant in Canada. It has, however, remained at the centre of controversy. In 1996, as a result of a PCB leak, and several other environmental issues, BOVAR was charged with multiple environmental infractions. In 1997, the U.S. removed a ban on the import of PCB waste, and BOVAR immediately faced stiff competition from U.S. facilities. By 1997, Swan Hills' profit had declined to $5.2 million. In 2000, BOVAR issued a notice of intent to cease operations due to its inability to make a profit. In 2001, the facility was returned to the province, and capital assets capital assets n. equipment, property, and funds owned by a business. (See: capital, capital account)  of approximately $34 million were written off by BOVAR. (41) In 2003, the government signed a ten-year operations contract with Earth Tech Inc., a division of Tyco International For the unrelated division of Mattel, see .

Tyco International Ltd. NYSE: TYC is a diversified manufacturing conglomerate incorporated in Bermuda, with United States operational headquarters in New Jersey.
 Ltd.

The contract's provisions provided a strong incentive for overcapitalization Overcapitalization

When a company has too much capital for the needs of its business.

Notes:
You might think that more capital is always better, but this isn't the case.
 because BOVAR's profits were a function of its capital investment rather than its cost-efficiency. As a result, BOVAR received a high guaranteed rate of return and its risk exposure was minimal. (42) In this P3, there was no effective transfer of risk during the first ten years, the contract was poorly designed in terms of incentives, there were enormous contracting costs, and the project was eventually terminated. Swan Hills cannot be counted as a P3 success.

Confederation Bridge

Prince Edward Island Prince Edward Island, province (2001 pop. 135,294), 2,184 sq mi (5,657 sq km), E Canada, off N.B. and N.S. Geography


One of the Maritime Provinces, Prince Edward Island lies in the Gulf of St.
 joined federation under a constitutional agreement that guaranteed ferry service in perpetuity Of endless duration; not subject to termination.

The phrase in perpetuity is often used in the grant of an Easement to a utility company.


in perpetuity adj. forever, as in one's right to keep the profits from the land in perpetuity.
. (43) In 1988, a plebiscite plebiscite (plĕb`ĭsīt) [Lat.,=popular decree], vote of the people on a question submitted to them, as in a referendum. The term, however, has acquired the more specific meaning of a popular vote concerning changes of sovereignty, as  approved a fixed link to replace the ferry service. Later that year, the federal government selected three bids for further development. Strait strait (strat) a narrow passage.

straits of pelvis  the pelvic inlet(superior pelvic s.) and pelvic outlet(inferior pelvic s.) .


strait
n.
 Crossing Development Inc. (SCDI SCDI Scottish Council of Development and Industry ), a multinational consortium submitted the winning bid. The selected bid was essentially a BOT ("build-operate-transfer") agreement. The contract specified a $41.9-million (1992 Canadian dollars) per annum Per annum

Yearly.
 payment from the federal government to the operator, notionally representing the avoided cost of ferry operation. Strait Crossing Development Inc. was entitled to the toll revenues for thirty-five years, after which bridge ownership and revenues reverted to the federal government. The government provided an annual $13.9-million revenue guarantee and agreed to bear a number of the residual risks. Principal financing was secured in 1993 through the sale of $640-million real return bonds by Strait Crossing Finance Inc. (SCFI SCFI Spruce Creek Fly-in (Daytona Beach, FL) ), which was established as a special purpose Crown corporation of New Brunswick. However, the federal government provided a guarantee for these bonds. Strait Crossing Finance Inc. initially took on most of the construction and operational risk, as well as toll revenue risk beyond the guarantee. Strait Crossing Development Inc. was required to post performance bonds and guarantees for specified contingencies. The bridge opened in 1997. Initial tolls were set at the ferry price for comparable vehicles and passengers. Annual increases are permitted at seventy-five per cent of the rate of consumer price inflation. The Canadian government estimated its incremental costs for project management to be $46 million.

This P3 is clearly a success to the extent that it delivered a functioning bridge on schedule. While there have been weather closures and some unexpected repairs, the bridge itself is functioning as expected. However, the project had high financing costs: the bonds were sold at a 4.5-per-cent interest rate, at a time when similar federal issues were priced at 4.1 per cent. Strait Crossing Finance Inc. also paid a sales commission of 1.75 per cent, compared to a rate of 0.6 per cent for federal real return bonds. The major problem with describing this P3 as a success is that the bonds were guaranteed by the federal government and thus there was no net reduction in risk exposure relative to on-budget financing. (44) It is difficult to escape the conclusion that the P3 was chosen primarily to achieve off-balance sheet financing.

Highway 407 Express Toll Route (ETR ETR Estimated Time of Return/Repair
ETR Early to Rise (health e-zine)
ETR Effective Tax Rate
Etr Etruscan (linguistics)
ETR Eastern Test Range
ETR Express Toll Route
)

Highway 407 is a 108-kilometre highway across the north of Metropolitan Toronto Metro Council redirects here. For the legislative body of Nashville, Tennessee, see Metropolitan Council (Davidson County). For a governmental body in Minnesota, see Metropolitan Council. . The request for proposals (RFP (Request For Proposal) A document that invites a vendor to submit a bid for hardware, software and/or services. It may provide a general or very detailed specification of the system.

1. (business) RFP - Request for Proposal.
2.
) was announced in 1993, when the Province of Ontario was emerging from a recession that had left it in an extremely weak financial position. (45) The recession and the province's high debt load made atoll road politically attractive. The original RFP proposed that the province would be responsible for land assembly and related costs, while the private partner would provide financing, guarantee a maximum construction price, and operate the highway. The private partner would be remunerated from toll revenues, but neither traffic levels nor toll revenues were guaranteed. Consequently, the private partner was financially exposed to the operating risk Operating risk

The inherent or fundamental risk of a firm, without regard to financial risk. The risk that is created by operating leverage. Also called business risk.
. The RFP specified few characteristics of the highway in order to encourage innovation.

In the responses to the RFP, it emerged that credible private partners were unwilling to assume the financing risks in addition to construction and operating risks. Indeed, both of the two qualified consortia sought extensive provincial backing for the project debt. Without a toll-revenue guarantee, a private firm would have been required to pay at least seventy-five basis points more for debt-financing than would the province. (46) As a result, the province assumed financing of the project. The province also retained the operational risk during the first eighteen months. This risk was only reduced when it sold the highway's operating concession to a Canadian-Spanish-Australian consortium for $3.1 billion. (47) The deal included a ninety-nine-year lease agreement, control of the highway and tolls (but with an initial year toll restriction provision). The operator was required to maintain the facility, meet all Ontario Ministry of Transportation safety standards Safety standards are standards designed to ensure the safety of products, activities or processes, etc. They may be advisory or compulsory and are normally laid down by an advisory or regulatory body that may be either voluntary or statutory.  and undergo random audits. It was also required to add lanes once pre-set traffic triggers were met.

The 1999 contract set maximum tolls for the first year of operation. However, the tolling agreement changed with the opening of eastern and western extensions. Over the first year of operations of the extended highway, a "base traffic flow" was set based on the peak-hour traffic volume; it was assumed this would grow by one to three per cent a year. If traffic volumes exceeded this threshold, tolls could be raised without restriction; if volumes were lower than the threshold, and tolls exceeded the threshold, the province could impose a penalty equal to twice the surplus of toll revenue charges above the threshold. (48) Since 1999, tolls have been raised six times, and in 2004 the consortium announced that it intended to raise tolls again, claiming it was losing money. (49) The toll increases dampened Highway 407 volumes, resulting in congestion The condition of a network when there is not enough bandwidth to support the current traffic load.

congestion - When the offered load of a data communication path exceeds the capacity.
 on adjacent roads. In February 2004, the government took legal action against Highway 407 Express Toll Route (ETR), claiming that it had breached its contract by raising tolls without government permission. The court sided with 407 ETR, and an independent arbitrator affirmed that 407 ETR had the authority to raise tolls without consulting the government. (50) After two unsuccessful legal attempts to have the contract re-drawn, the province was granted permission to take the case to the Ontario Court of Appeal The Court of Appeal for Ontario (frequently referred to as Ontario Court of Appeal) is headquartered in downtown Toronto, in historic Osgoode Hall.

The Court is composed of 22 judges who hear over 1 500 appeals each year, on issues of private law, constitutional
. In March 2005, however, Ontario and 407 ETR came to an agreement. The consortium agreed to implement a $40-million "customer-benefit program," reducing tolls by up to fifteen per cent for 100,000 frequent users over the next four years and providing discounts for truck drivers during evenings and weekends. In exchange, the government withdrew its demand for atoll rate rollback A DBMS feature that reverses the current transaction out of the database, returning the data to its former state. A rollback is performed when processing a transaction fails at some point, and it is necessary to start over. See two-phase commit. . The agreement allows 407 ETR to raise tolls once the rebate program for regular users is in place, which was scheduled for 2007. (51)

Highway 407 was constructed quickly, without major cost overruns and now generates approximately 300,000 daily vehicle trips. The design process did appear to save substantial provincial expenditures during the construction phase, perhaps in the order of $300 million. (52) However, some of these savings were not realized because design changes were instituted before the highway opened. These changes were paid for by Ontario, since they were not part of the initial contract; the actual extent of any savings is therefore unclear. Land assembly and construction costs were reduced by innovative design features, such as short entrances and narrow radius ramps, though there were concerns in the early stages that these changes could jeopardize jeop·ard·ize  
tr.v. jeop·ard·ized, jeop·ard·iz·ing, jeop·ard·izes
To expose to loss or injury; imperil. See Synonyms at endanger.
 safety. (53) The concerns stemmed from issues such as conversion of dual exit lanes to a single exit lane and the use of asphalt paving rather than concrete. (54)

The initial major weakness of 407 as a P3 was the failure of the government to effectively transfer financing risks: the construction phase became a conventional "develop-design-and-build" contract, with the private partner tendering a fixed-price construction project. Even so, ongoing transaction costs have been extremely high. The 407 operators, not surprisingly, have been interested in maximizing profits rather than optimizing Metropolitan Toronto traffic flows. At the same time, Ontario appears to have behaved opportunistically when political costs escalated because of the toll increases. Those who focus on the lack of risk transfer, such as Joan Price Boase, regard it as a P3 failure. (55) Chandran Mylvaganam and Sandford Borins present a more charitable, mixed assessment. (56)

Highway 104 Western Alignment Project

Highway 104 (Cobequid Pass) is a forty-five-kilometre toll highway through the Cobequid Mountains in northern Nova Scotia. It was built to replace a congested con·gest·ed
adj.
Affected with or characterized by congestion.


congested ENT adjective Referring to a boggy blood-filled tissue. See Nasal congestion.
 portion of the Trans Canada Highway Trans Canada Highway can refer to:
  • Trans-Canada Highway, the Canadian highway system
  • Trans Canada Highway (EP), a release from electronic music duo Boards of Canada
 that had claimed the lives of fifty people over a ten-year period. The (Liberal) government's primary objectives were to retain ownership of the highway and to finance it solely from toll revenue, without having to guarantee debt. In 1995, the province created the Highway 104 Western Alignment Corporation (104 WAC WAC (Women's Army Corps), U.S. army organization created (1942) during World War II to enlist women as auxiliaries for noncombatant duty in the U.S. army. Before 1943 it was known as the Women's Auxiliary Army Corps (WAAC). Its first director was Oveta Culp Hobby. ) to allow for "non-recourse" financing. An RFP was issued to three qualified groups. Atlantic Highways Management Corporation Ltd. (AHMC AHMC Anti-Helicopter Mine Countermeasures ), a subsidiary of Atlantic Highways Corporation Inc., was selected as the P3 private partner. (57)

Atlantic Highways Management Corporation received a management fee to cover the cost of operations, while 104 WAC was responsible for the financing and oversight of the design, construction, and operation of the highway. The only source of revenue for 104 WAC was to be from tolls for thirty years. The financing included $121 million for construction, operations and maintenance costs. Private-sector bondholders provided $61 million; the federal and provincial governments provided $27.5 million each; and Sydney Steel Corporation Sydney Steel Corporation (SYSCO) is a Crown corporation in the Canadian province of Nova Scotia. History
An integrated steel mill was established on the southeast side of Sydney Harbour in the Whitney Pier neighbourhood of Sydney, Nova Scotia in 1901 by American investors.
 pension fund invested $5 million in subordinated notes. (58) The highway was designed and completed in 1997, in less than twenty months. Although 104 WAC was to be responsible for traffic shortfalls, in fact, "traffic ... has exceeded all expectations." (59) This is not totally surprising, because, although the province would not formally guarantee traffic volumes, "the final agreement required the Province to compel large trucks to use the road, to maintain a 30 km per hour speed differential between the old and new road, and to agree to several obligations regarding traffic enforcement." (60) In 1999, the Conservatives won the provincial election, and the premier-elect claimed that he would "love" to eliminate tolls completely. (61) Although the new government did not in fact eliminate tolls, it has "negotiated" with 104 WAC to ameliorate a·mel·io·rate  
tr. & intr.v. a·me·lio·rat·ed, a·me·lio·rat·ing, a·me·lio·rates
To make or become better; improve. See Synonyms at improve.



[Alteration of meliorate.
 previously scheduled toll increases, following intense pressure from the N.S. Trucker's Association to do SO. (62)

The auditor general Auditor general may refer to,
  • Comptroller and Auditor-General
  • Auditor General for Scotland
  • Auditor General of Canada
  • Auditor General of Pakistan
 of Nova Scotia argued that the highway project did deliver some benefits to the province and that debt service charges for the loan would have been lower if the province had borrowed the funds directly, rather than using a P3, but the province would have assumed greater risk. As mentioned earlier, however, the auditor general also argued that the project debt should be treated as ordinary provincial debt. The province, not surprisingly, did not agree, as this would have negated the whole purpose of the exercise.

Although Highway 104 is usually described as a P3, the main "private partner"--104 WAC--is actually a government entity; so much so that the auditor general argued that its debt should be regarded as provincial debt. Given that it is a government entity, it not surprising that 104 WAC agreed to give up previously mandated toll increases. In December 2005, 104 WAC signed an agreement with the province giving it discretion to hold back future toll increases. Furthermore, 104 WAC is expected to use any "surplus" revenues to reduce future toll increases or pay down the corporation's debt, provided it "maintains certain financial targets." (63) One normally does not have to incentivize in·cen·tiv·ize  
tr.v. in·cen·tiv·ized, in·cen·tiv·iz·ing, in·cen·tiv·iz·es
To offer incentives or an incentive to; motivate:
 a private partner in a P3 to maintain financial targets. Clearly, by 2006, the balance of expenditure costs and political costs had changed considerably. It could be argued that the main purpose of the 104 WAC exercise was to allow the province to access private debt--but in a manner that, at least in hindsight, has involved moderately high transaction costs.

Evergreen Park School

In 1994, the Government of New Brunswick decided to structure the Evergreen Park School project as a P3. In 1995, Greenarm Corporation of Fredericton was selected to negotiate a final agreement. (64) Greenarm formed a separate subsidiary, named Greenarm Schools Ltd., to manage the project. The contract included a twenty-five-year lease-purchase arrangement, with an option to purchase at that time for $2.5 million, renew the lease for a further ten-year term or walk away. (65) Greenarm was responsible for constructing, insuring, maintaining and operating the school for the length of the lease; however, the company contracted-out the construction. Financing was obtained at 9.065 per cent per annum. (66) The school opened in the fall of 1996 and accommodated approximately 800 students. Greenarm handles the garbage collection A software routine that searches memory for areas of inactive data and instructions in order to reclaim that space for the general memory pool (the heap). Operating systems may or may not provide this feature. , cleaning, grounds maintenance, snow removal, and painting. Greenarm has the exclusive right to use the school's plant and technology after 3 p.m. From 3 p.m. to 6 p.m., it operates a for-profit remedial and enrichment program for children. After 6 p.m., it runs similar programs for adults. (67) These activities all involve some opportunity cost, but it is not obvious what the appropriate counterfactual should be in assessing this cost.

Evergreen was essentially a "finance-build-operate-transfer" project. In order to assess the "value for money" of this P3, New Brunswick attempted to estimate the costs that it would have incurred if it had undertaken the project. The province claimed that its capital costs would have been $9.4 million, while Greenarm's costs had come in at roughly $10 million. The auditor general, however, argued that the province's capital costs would have been closer to $9.2 million. (68) He argued the two modes of operations would yield the same costs in aggregate. (69) The province had included transaction costs associated with administering the P3 in projecting its costs, which the auditor general argued were not incremental. Also, he claimed that although the province had projected its cleaning labour costs under an assumption that it would use the local union, the province was under no obligation to do so for a new school. (70) This is debatable de·bat·a·ble  
adj.
1. Being such that formal argument or discussion is possible.

2. Open to dispute; questionable.

3. In dispute, as land or territory claimed by more than one country.
, as the province had agreed to waive its right to use contracted staff. Excluding the deduction in staffing costs, the province would have had higher operating costs operating costs nplgastos mpl operacionales , by roughly $34,000 per year. (71)

This case study illustrates some of the difficulties of even calculating the costs of P3 provision, compared to direct government provision, especially when the private-sector partner engages in uses that the public sector would not. On one hand, these activities may be innovative; on the other hand, they may involve social opportunity costs Opportunity costs

The difference in the actual performance of a particular investment and some other desired investment adjusted for fixed costs and execution costs. It often refers to the most valuable alternative that is given up.
 (in this case, foregone fore·gone
v.
Past participle of forego1.

adj.
Having gone before; previous.

Usage Note: The word foregone has recently developed a new meaning as a truncation of the phrase
 use of school property outside of regular school hours).

O'Connell Drive Elementary School

O'Connell Drive Elementary School was opened in 1997. It was a pilot for thirty-nine schools that were to be built under Nova Scotia's P3 program for school development. The developer, Nova Learning Inc., purchased the land from the province and leased it to Canapen Limited, a pension fund, for twenty years TWENTY YEARS. The lapse of twenty years raises a presumption of certain facts, and after such a time, the party against whom the presumption has been raised, will be required to prove a negative to establish his rights.
     2.
. Canapen constructed the building and purchased the equipment. In 1998, the province and Canapen entered into a twenty-year lease for the facility, for an annual payment of approximately $700,000. (72) The Halifax School Board signed an operations agreement with an independent contractor A person who contracts to do work for another person according to his or her own processes and methods; the contractor is not subject to another's control except for what is specified in a mutually binding agreement for a specific job. , Oxford Atlantic, for property management and maintenance. In addition to monthly payments, the school board pays an annual administration fee of fifteen per cent of expenses. (73) The province is responsible for costs incurred from operations, as well as repairs and capital improvements. (74)

The private partners' combined purchase price was approximately $8 million, (75) roughly the same amount it would have cost the province to finance the school with provincial debt. (76) At the end of the contract, Nova will retain the land, building and equipment, unless the province either 1) purchases the facility from Nova for $3,950,000 (the N.S. auditor general estimates that the present value of this amount is $1.1 million) or 2) renews the lease for up to two five-year terms at an amount that will amortize the $3,950,000 (plus interest) over ten years.

The extent of risk transfer in the agreement was quite limited. Nova will have recovered almost all of its initial investment if the N.S. government walks away after twenty years and it will still own the land and buildings. (77) The province retains the usage risk for twenty years and the public sector is responsible for capital improvements. The risk of construction cost overruns was held by Nova, as there was a fixed price construction agreement. (78) As in the Evergreen case, Nova retains the right to use the schools after hours Adv. 1. after hours - not during regular hours; "he often worked after hours" , on weekends and during summers for programs, such as technology-related training courses. (79)

O'Connell Drive was to be a model to create "schools of the future." As the project unfolded, however, problems arose. First, the provincial government could not come to an agreement with Nova regarding the financial terms of the lease. The province was initially unable to negotiate the financial terms that would allow it to finance the school off its balance sheet. Nonetheless, the province proceeded with the project without a signed lease agreement, which was eventually signed more than a year after the school was opened. This gave the consortium considerable leverage over the province when negotiating the terms. There were claims that developers were locating schools adjacent to property that they already owned, rather than where needs were greatest. (80)

Ultimately, the provincial auditor general argued that the lease should be recorded as a capital lease and the liabilities recorded as a provincial debt and that the government's goal had primarily been to remove new school building costs from the balance sheet in order to reduce the apparent size of the deficit. (81) There was also a widespread perception that the contract terms were primarily advantageous to the private partners, which gradually raised political costs for the government. In 2000, the Nova Scotia government bowed to political pressure and abandoned school P3s. The thirty-eight P3 schools that were built cost $32 million more than projected. (82)

In these P3s, the degree of risk transfer was minimal. Transaction costs also appear to have been high. While it is difficult to decisively conclude that there were no construction cost-savings (an appropriate counterfactual on direct government procurement Government procurement, also called public tendering, is the procurement of goods and services on behalf of a public authority, such as a government agency. With 10 to 15% of GDP in developed countries, and up to 20% in developing countries, government procurement accounts  would necessarily be speculative), it is certainly unlikely there were major cost-savings. Clearly, O'Connell Drive was not successful from a political perspective. While political costs of the P3 appeared low ex ante, they certainly turned out to be high ex post and essentially forced the abandonment of P3 for school construction.

Britannia Mine Water Treatment Plant

The Britannia Mine is located forty-eight kilometres north of Vancouver, on Howe Sound Howe Sound is a roughly triangular sound, actually a network of fjords situated immediately northwest of Vancouver. Geography
Howe Sound's mouth at the Strait of Georgia is situated between West Vancouver, and the Sunshine Coast.
. Mining over many years had resulted in acid rock drainage into the sound and heavy-metal pollution. (83) In 2001, the Government of British Columbia entered into an agreement with the former mine operators whereby they contributed $30 million towards the remediation of the site in exchange for a guarantee that they would not be held liable for further site clean up. A key component of the mine remediation project was a water treatment plant. (84) In October 2003, the province decided to structure this treatment plant as a P3, and EPCOR was selected as the P3 partner, based primarily on cost, technical criteria and qualitative assessment. (85)

The contract was to design and build the plant within a year, together with a twenty-year maintenance contract. The total discounted cost was $27.2 million, plus cash allowances of $1.9 million (estimated public expenditure was $39.7 million). Payments are based on water volume, water quality, input prices and actual capital costs. The province retains ownership of the facility and residual environmental liabilities. P3 partner EPCOR financed and built the plant, and it bore financing, construction, operations and maintenance. The facility treats about twelve million litres of mine runoff Runoff

The procedure of printing the end-of-day prices for every stock on an exchange onto ticker tape.

Notes:
If the "tape is late" then it can take a long time to print off all the closing prices.
 per day, removing about 66,000 kilograms of copper per year. Electricity produced from the mine's discharge flow is used to help power the treatment plant. (86) The province shares in revenue generated from future innovation. In the event of default, the province retains the right to intellectual property stemming from the plant, which can be used only in the plant. (87)

There have been no significant issues with EPCOR to this point. Many of the key milestones were completed safely and on time. The plant was started up in compliance with interim operating requirements in October 2005. The project has been fully operational since early 2006. There have been some delays, such as a delay in successfully completing high flow tests to demonstrate maximum system flow capacity, as well as minor operational glitches. The net present value life-cycle cost of the project is $27.2 million, which has been estimated to be $10 million less than the estimated cost of completing the plant by traditional methods. (88)

Britannia appears to represent a reasonably successful P3. Indeed, given the specialized technical requirements of the project, it is hard to conceive of Verb 1. conceive of - form a mental image of something that is not present or that is not the case; "Can you conceive of him as the president?"
envisage, ideate, imagine
 this project being conducted in-house by government. On the other hand, this is the kind of project that has traditionally been contracted-out in one form or another.

Moncton Water Treatment Facility

In the 1990s, the City of Moncton needed a new water filtration plant. The city was unable to obtain provincial or federal funding and decided to go with a P3. (89) In 1996, Moncton began a competitive bid process to select a firm to design, build, operate and maintain a new water treatment facility. Three consortia submitted final proposals. In April 1998, Greater Moncton Water Ltd., a New Brunswick-incorporated company owned by USFilter Canada, Inc. (USF USF University of South Florida
USF Universal Service Fund (often part of phone bill in US)
USF University of San Francisco
USF University of Sioux Falls
USF University of St.
) (eighty-five per cent) and Hardman Group Limited (fifteen per cent), was awarded the twenty-year contract. USFilter Canada had significant experience and expertise building and maintaining such plants, as it manages over 260 facilities across North America North America, third largest continent (1990 est. pop. 365,000,000), c.9,400,000 sq mi (24,346,000 sq km), the northern of the two continents of the Western Hemisphere.  and is a subsidiary of Vivendi. (90)

USFilter Canada contracted to build the plant within 500 days, lease the facility back to the city, and to maintain the facility. Moncton had an option to purchase the plant by requiring that USF pay the lease and licensing fees up front in an amount equal to the $23.1-million cost of the plant. Moncton has legal ownership of the facility, but pays USF $3,362,263 per year to cover lease costs, including capital costs (fixed at $223,417 per year), operating costs, capital repair, and replacement reserves. Moncton also pays for chemical costs, electricity and sludge handling, which brings the total annual payment to over $4 million. (91) USFilter Canada provides a $15-million guarantee to the City of Moncton. A repair and replacement program was built into the contract to ensure that the facility would be in good repair once returned to the city. User-costs are determined by city council, except where related to factors outside of the control of either partner, such as the cost associated with sediment removal. The treatment facility must meet specified performance targets, which it has met so far. USFilter Canada assumed all construction and design risk associated with the project.

The water treatment plant construction was completed in eighteen months and began operation in 2005. The cost of the facility represents $91 per residential unit per year, compared to the city's projected cost of $111 per residential unit per year. To date, there have been no complaints about the system. The water is high quality, but residents pay higher water fees than they were paying prior to 1999. Between 1995 and 1999, water fees increased by up to seven per cent on an annual basis. Between 1999 and 2000, however, water charges increased by seventy-five per cent. Proponents argued, however, that the rate represents an 11.2-per-cent saving for taxpayers, since the cost was expected to be $33 million if the facility had been built as a public-sector initiative. (92) Moncton also claimed that the total cost of the water treatment plant would be $23.1 million, compared to $32.8 million if the city had financed the plant, although the $32.8 million was based on a proposal to build a plant that would have had three times the water capacity of the one built. It is likely that significant savings were realized as a result of USF's Trident water filtration process, which allowed the company to reduce the facility's size by forty per cent. (93)

Cranbrook Civic Arena Multiplex

In the mid-1990s, Cranbrook decided that it needed a new recreational facility Noun 1. recreational facility - a public facility for recreation
recreation facility

facility, installation - a building or place that provides a particular service or is used for a particular industry; "the assembly plant is an enormous facility"
 that included a hockey arena, swimming pools and other amenities. The project was estimated to cost over $20 million. The city decided on a P3. (94) In a 1999 referendum on the P3, a narrow margin voted in favour. Cranbrook signed a thirty-year "design-build-finance-lease-operate-and-transfer" agreement with KeenRose Technology Group. (95) The contract stipulated that the private financing rate was not to exceed 7.25 per cent. (96) However, securing such financing proved to be difficult. After a three-month delay, Sunlife Financial Service and Pacific Insurance split the loan with KeenRose, and construction began in October 1999. The city provided the land and leased back the aquatic centre for $800,000 per year. There was a variable revenue guarantee of $700,000, and the operator was guaranteed the first $142,000 of its costs. KeenRose assumed the risk associated with the operating costs of approximately $1.5 million and guaranteed the capital cost of the facility at $22.6 million. The following year, KeenRose was purchased by Cinergy Corporation, which formed a separate subsidiary (Vestar Inc.) to manage the complex. (97)

Under the operations agreement, the city was allocated 1,500 hours per year of arena time, with the balance available to Vestar to sell at $125 per hour. (98) In 2001, the mayor announced a further 10.9-per-cent tax increase linked to a $500,000 construction cost overrun Noun 1. cost overrun - excess of cost over budget; "the cost overrun necessitated an additional allocation of funds in the budget"
cost - the total spent for goods or services including money and time and labor
 at the multiplex. In October 2001, Vestar complained that its costs were higher than anticipated and its revenue lower. For example, revenues from concerts and special events were far below projections. Faced with Vestar's weak financial position, the city agreed to cover revenue shortfalls beyond $140,000. (99) In 2002, the city auditor decided to include the $22-million lease on the city's financial statements, resulting in a substantial decrease in the city's borrowing power.

After dealing with legal disputes, cost overruns and construction delays, rive rive  
v. rived, riv·en also rived, riv·ing, rives

v.tr.
1. To rend or tear apart.

2. To break into pieces, as by a blow; cleave or split asunder.

3.
 years after the project began, the P3 was terminated. Vestar withdrew in 2004 after paying the city $1.7 million to take over ownership of the complex. (100) The complex proved to be much more costly than projected, and the city was not effectively able to protect itself against this eventuality e·ven·tu·al·i·ty  
n. pl. e·ven·tu·al·i·ties
Something that may occur; a possibility.


eventuality
Noun

pl -ties
 through the use of a P3. Cranbrook found itself with the highest debt level in the province.

Waterloo Landfill Gas Power Plant

Waterloo Landfill has been owned and operated by the Regional Municipality of Waterloo (RMOW RMOW Resort Municipality of Whistler (Canada) ) since its opening in 1972. The landfill has the capacity to produce methane gas until the middle of the 21st century. A plan developed in 1993 included a landfill gas (LFG LFG Landfill Gas
LFG Lincoln Financial Group (insurance & financial planning company)
LFG Looking For Group (Everquest)
LFG Lexical-Functional Grammar (computational linguistics) 
) utilization facility. (101) The RMOW elected not to own or operate the facility, primarily due to a lack of relevant expertise. Following an RFP in 1995, RMOW awarded Toromont Energy the contract to design, build, own and operate the facility. Toromont provided the financing for design and construction ($7 million). In exchange, Toromont has the right to utilize the LFG for twenty-two years. There is an annual royalty to the RMOW, based on the revenue from the sale of electricity to Ontario Power Generation Ontario Power Generation (OPG) is a public company whose shares are wholly owned by the Government of Ontario. It is responsible for approximately 70% of the electricity generation in the province of Ontario, Canada [1]. . The municipality does not guarantee the supply of LFG. The contract requires that the facility be on-line ninety per cent of the time that the RMOW is supplying LFG to the facility. If this guarantee is not met, Toromont must pay the municipality an amount equivalent to the royalty that would have resulted if the plant had been running at ninety-per-cent capacity.

Toromont was not able to sign the contract until 1997 due to difficulty in obtaining an agreement with Ontario Hydro Ontario Hydro was the official name from 1974 of the Hydro-Electric Power Commission of Ontario which was established in 1906 by the provincial Power Commission Act to build transmission lines to supply municipal utilities with electricity generated by private companies  on selling the energy to the power grid. (102) Construction began in December 1998, and the plant was operational in September 1999. Since the facility became fully operational, the system has been running ninety-nine per cent of the time. (103) It is expected that the royalties may grow to approximately $500,000 as greater amounts of LFG are collected. The project is expected to have a capital payback Payback

The length of time it takes to recover the initial cost of a project, without regard to the time value of money.
 of less than ten years. (104) To date, no concerns have been reported with regard to the partnership. Since the facility is located on leased Crown land, it is unclear which of the two partners will retain ownership of the facility at the end of the contract.

Analysis of Canadian P3 case studies

Earlier, we argued that the major potential benefit of P3s derives from the private sector's ability to deliver projects at lower cost. However, we also pointed out that the appropriate test from a social perspective is whether P3s have lower total social costs, including production costs and all transaction costs and externalities associated with managing external suppliers (including construction). The case studies clearly indicate that the transaction costs associated with ex ante or ex post contracting in P3s often make it difficult for society to actually realize lower total social costs.

It is useful to consider the specific dimensions and externalities of trans action cost discussed earlier. (105) Table 2 summarizes our assessment of the values of these transaction cost factors in each of the case studies. The factors are as follows: the degree of asset specificity; construction complexity (essentially whether the project involved a standard production technology); construction cost risk transferred to the private partner; use-risk uncertainty; use-risk transferred to the private partner; contract management skills of the government partner; and the extent to which externalities were imposed on third parties. The table also includes an estimate of the level of transaction costs for each of the ten P3 and an overall assessment of "success" as a P3.

We review each transaction cost factor in turn. In practice, all of these projects have high asset specificity; thus, the likelihood of opportunistic hold-up was high in all of these projects. We next consider the construction (cost) side and then the use- (revenue) side. Complexity refers to the difficulty of the project itself as well as to the difficulty of performance measurement. For infrastructure P3s, complexity pertains primarily to construction complexity. None of the projects studied here were especially different from previous projects, and quality was reasonably straightforward to monitor and measure. Thus, no project was highly complex. The school and building construction projects were low in complexity, while the highway projects, the bridge, and the water treatment plants were moderately complex. One might, therefore, expect that the public sector would be able to transfer all of the construction risk to the private sector, but this did not occur in two of the cases. In the Alberta Special Waste Management System, the government retained some construction cost risk due to poor contract management skills. In the Cranbrook Arena case, the government ended up paying for cost overruns, presumably pre·sum·a·ble  
adj.
That can be presumed or taken for granted; reasonable as a supposition: presumable causes of the disaster.
 because of a combination of poor contract management skills and changes in political costs.

Consideration of revenue risk is more complicated. While most of these projects appear to have been relatively predictable from a construction cost perspective, they were highly uncertain from a usage, and consequently, revenue perspective. Part of government's motivation for P3s has certainly been to transfer this risk to the private sector. However, it is not clear that the private sector is any more willing or able to accept this risk than the public sector. Also, the operating risk may be higher for the private sector than for government. This is because it is relatively easy for the government to affect usage, either positively or negatively. For example, the government compelled large trucks to use Highway 104, thereby helping its "partner." But government can hurt its partner.

Given that the private sector is not keen to take on revenue risk, it is not surprising that government has been unsuccessful in transferring this risk. While this is summarized in Table 2, it is shown in more detail in Figure 1. It suggests that the higher the revenue uncertainty (on the vertical axis), the lower the actual transfer of risk to the private sector (the horizontal axis). For example, the government was able to transfer most of the risk to the private sector for the Evergreen Park School and the Waterloo Landfill Gas Power Plant, but the level of revenue uncertainty in both projects was low. Where the level of revenue uncertainty was higher, as in the two highway projects and Confederation Bridge, the private sector simply would not take on revenue risk. The two projects in the middle of Figure 1 (Alberta Special Waste Management and Moncton Water Treatment Facility) have medium uncertainty and some risk transfer. There is a tendency, therefore, for projects to lie close to a line running from the top left-hand portion of the diagram to the bottom right. According to according to
prep.
1. As stated or indicated by; on the authority of: according to historians.

2. In keeping with: according to instructions.

3.
 this view, the two outliers are Britannia Mine and O'Connell Drive School. Britannia Mine is in relatively early days and we do not yet have full information about this project. The O'Connell Drive School project clearly had poor contract management.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

The three projects with the highest use-uncertainty (those in the top left-hand corner) also happen to be the largest projects, as indicated by the size of the "circles." The private sector may be especially unwilling to take on revenue risk when projects are large.

Transactions costs are likely to be high when asset specificity is high, construction complexity is high, revenue uncertainty is high, and contract management effectiveness is poor. This is exacerbated when, in addition, government tries to transfer construction cost risk and operating revenue operating revenue

Revenue from any regular source. Revenue from sales is adjusted for discounts and returns when calculating operating revenue. Compare other revenue.
 risk. These problems are compounded and transactions costs are higher if the construction risks and revenue risks are high and these costs are transferred to the private sector.

The Alberta Special Waste Management System exhibited high transactions costs--because asset specificity was high, complexity was moderate, use-uncertainty was moderate, and contract management was poor. These factors, combined with attempts to pass on some of the construction risk and use-risk, resulted in negative externalities and high transactions costs. If is a clear failure from a social perspective. The Confederation Bridge project was of high asset specificity, moderate complexity and high use-risk. Thus, there was the potential for high transaction costs. However, contract management effectiveness was fairly good. Still, while construction risk was transferred to the private sector, use-risk was not. As a result, the transaction costs were moderate, and this project can be considered a qualified success. Highway 407 ETR had high asset specificity, moderate complexity, and high use-uncertainty; consequently, like Confederation Bridge, it potentially had high transaction costs. In this case, contract management effectiveness was also poor. The result was significant negative impacts on highway users and adjacent highways, resulting in high transaction costs. Although the production costs were reasonable, the negative externalities and high transaction costs lead us to conclude that this project was "poor" from a social perspective.

Conclusion

Some of reasons why governments are drawn to P3s clearly have some validity--especially lower construction costs. However, even if valid, it is important to emphasize that from a social perspective the key issue is whether the total cost, including production costs and all contracting costs, is lower for the P3 than the total cost of government provision. To investigate this issue, we developed a positive theory perspective of P3s, based primarily on analysis of partners' goals and transaction cost economics. We then partially tested this theory on ten Canadian infrastructure P3s--all those for which we could gather reasonable information from secondary sources. The evidence suggests that the benefits are often outweighed by contract costs and externalities.

A note of caution is that our case selection is based on the availability of public information. Conflict and problems are inherently more newsworthy news·wor·thy  
adj. news·wor·thi·er, news·wor·thi·est
Of sufficient interest or importance to the public to warrant reporting in the media.



news
 than cooperation and everyday delivery of services; thus, we cannot claim that this is an unbiased sample of P3s. However, it does include all P3s where we could draw upon reasonably independent information.

The evidence from Canadian P3s indicates that the willingness of private-sector firms to bear use-risk declines with the level of use-risk. Private-sector firms will not participate in a P3 if it bears cost risk and large use- (revenue) risk. Thus, it is not surprising that emerging evidence from the U.K. (106) and Australia (107) have also found that other governments have not been very successful at shifting risk to the private partners. Nor is it surprising that contract negotiations associated with attempts to shift risk were extremely costly. (108)

Our analysis suggests that, in some sense, effective P3s are not P3s! Private-sector project participation makes the most sense when it bears cost risks, but not revenue risks. In such circumstances, there is not that much difference from what has traditionally been described as a "build-operate-transfer" contract. While the private sector often has potential cost advantages for the construction part of the contract, these may not extend to the operating part of the contract. Indeed, during the operating phase, the private sector is more likely to face opportunistic behaviour from the government than would a government agency if it operated the project. Thus, we suggest limiting the scope of future P3 contracts. Of course, if the private-sector partner is being compensated for risk, public-sector managers must then ensure that they actually bear it.

Notes

(1) The United Kingdom has produced the most extensive research. A sample of the studies include Jane Broadbent, Jas Gill and Richard Laughlin, "The development of contracting in the context of infrastructure investment in the U.K.: The case of the Private Finance Initiative in the National Health Service," International Public Management Journal 6, no. 2 (2003), pp. 173-97; Paul A. Grout Grout

A binding or structural agent used in construction and engineering applications. Grout is typically a mixture of hydraulic cement and water, with or without fine aggregate; however, chemical grouts are also produced.
 and Margaret Stevens, "The assessment: Financing and managing public services Public services is a term usually used to mean services provided by government to its citizens, either directly (through the public sector) or by financing private provision of services. ," Oxford Review of Economic Policy Oxford Review of Economic Policy is a refereed journal which is published quarterly. Each issue concentrates on a current theme in economic policy, with a balance between macro- and microeconomics, and comprises an assessment and a number of articles.  19, no. 2 (Summer 2003), pp. 215-34; Michael Pollitt Michael Pollitt (born February 29, 1972 in Farnworth, Lancashire), is an English professional football player. Pollitt, a goalkeeper, currently plays for Wigan Athletic.[1] Career
Wigan acquired his services from Rotherham United in June 2005.
, "Learning from UK private finance initiative experience," in Graeme Hodge and Carsten Greve, eds., The Challenge of Public-Private Partnerships: Learning from International Experience (Cheltenham, U.K.: Edward Elgar Sir Edward William Elgar, 1st Baronet, OM, GCVO (2 June 1857 – 23 February 1934) was an English Romantic composer. Several of his first major orchestral works, including the Enigma Variations and the Pomp and Circumstance Marches, were greeted with acclaim. , 2005), pp. 207-30; and Jean Shaoul, "The private finance initiative or the public funding Public funding is money given from tax revenue or other governmental sources to an individual, organization, or entity. See also
  • Public funding of sports venues
  • Research funding
  • Funding body
 of private profit?" in Hodge and Greve, The Challenge of Public-Private Partnerships, pp. 190-206.

(2) See Eoin Reeves, "Public-private partnerships in Ireland: Policy and practice," Public Money and Management 23, no. 3 (July-September 2003), pp. 163-70.

(3) Erik-Hans Klijn and Geert Teisman, "Institutional and strategic barriers to public-private partnerships: An analysis of Dutch cases," Public Money and Management 23, no. 3 (July-September 2003), pp. 137-46.

(4) Carsten Greve and Niels Ejersbo, "When public-private partnerships fail--the extreme case of the NPM-inspired local government of Farum in Denmark." Paper delivered for Nordisk Kommunalforskningskonference, Odense, Denmark, 29 November-1 December 2003.

(5) See Linda M. English, "Using public-private partnerships to deliver social infrastructure: The Australian experience," pp. 290-304, and Graeme A. Hodge, "Public-private partnerships: The Australasian experience with physical infrastructure," pp. 305-31, both in Hodge and Greve, The Challenge of Public-Private Partnerships.

(6) On this, see, for example, Herschel Hardin Herschel Hardin (born 1936) is a British Columbia-based writer, playwright, commentator and political activist and consultant best known for having contested the leadership of the New Democratic Party of Canada in 1995. , A Nation Unaware: The Canadian Economic Culture (Vancouver: J.J. Douglas, 1974); and Chandran Mylvaganam and Sandford Borins, If You Build It: Business, Government and Ontario's Electronic Highway (Toronto: University Centre for Public Management, 2004).

(7) These rationales are more fully described in Aidan R. Vining, Anthony E. Boardman and Finn Poschmann, "Public-private partnerships in the U.S. and Canada: There are no 'free lunches,'" Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis 7, no. 3 (September 2005), pp. 199-220.

(8) See Michael L. Marlow and David Joulfaian, "The determinants of off-budget activity of state and local governments," Public Choice 63, no. 2 (November 1989), pp. 113-23.

(9) For a review, see John Quiggin, "Public-private partnerships: Options for improved risk allocation," The Australian Economic Review 38, no. 4 (December 2005), pp. 445-50.

(10) Harry Kitchen, "A state of disrepair: How to fix the financing of municipal infrastructure in Canada," C.D. Howe Commentary 241 (December 2006), available at http://www.cdhowe. org/pdf/commentary_241.pdf.

(11) There is not much literature on this topic, but see James Leigland and Rosalind H. Thomas, "Municipal bonds as alternatives to PPPs: Facilitating direct municipal access to private capital," Development Southern Africa 16, no. 4 (October 1999), pp. 197-219.

(12) Michael Jensen Michael Cole Jensen joined the of the Harvard Business School in 1990. Currently, he is the managing director in charge of organizational strategy at Monitor Group, a strategy consulting firm.  and William Meckling, "Theory of the firm: Managerial behaviour, agency costs and ownership structure," Journal of Financial Economics 3, no. 4 (December 1976), pp. 305-60.

(13) Giovanni Dosi ''This article or section is being rewritten at

Giovanni Dosi is Professor of Economics at the Scuola Superiore Sant'Anna in Pisa, where he also coordinates the Doctoral Program in Economics and Management and leads the Laboratory of Economics and Management
, "Sources, procedures, and microeconomic mi·cro·ec·o·nom·ics  
n. (used with a sing. verb)
The study of the operations of the components of a national economy, such as individual firms, households, and consumers.
 effects of innovation," Journal of Economic Literature 26, no. 3 (September 1988), pp. 1120-171.

(14) See Greg Hundley, "Public- and private-sector occupational pay structures," Industrial Relations industrial relations
pl.n.
Relations between the management of an industrial enterprise and its employees.


industrial relations
Noun, pl

the relations between management and workers
 30, no. 3 (Fall 1991), pp. 417-34; and Robert G. Gregory and Jeff Borland, "Recent developments in public sector labor markets," in Orley Ashenfelter Orley Ashenfelter is a Frisch Medal winning economist who analyzed the results of the Judgment of Paris wine tasting event with Richard E. Quandt. [1] Ashenfelter serves as a professor of economics at Princeton University.[2].  and David Card David Edward Card is a Canadian labor economist and professor at the University of California, Berkeley.

Card earned his B.A. from Queen's University in 1978 and his Ph.D. in Economics in 1983 from Princeton University.
, eds., Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 3C (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1999), pp. 3573-630.

(15) See, for example, Bent Flyvbjerg Bent Flyvbjerg is Professor of Planning at Aalborg University, Denmark. He holds a concurrent position as Chair of Infrastructure Policy and Planning at Delft University of Technology, The Netherlands. , Mette Skamris Holm holm  
n. Chiefly British
An island in a river.



[Middle English, from Old Norse h
 and Soren Buhl, "Underestimating costs in public works public works
pl.n.
Construction projects, such as highways or dams, financed by public funds and constructed by a government for the benefit or use of the general public.

Noun 1.
 projects: Error or lie?," Journal of the American Planning Association 68, no. 3 (Summer 2002), pp. 279-93; Alan A. Altshuler and David E. Luberoff, Mega-Projects: The Changing Politics of Urban Public Investment (Washington, D.C: Brookings Institution Brookings Institution, at Washington, D.C.; chartered 1927 as a consolidation of the Institute for Government Research (est. 1916), the Institute of Economics (est. 1922), and the Robert S. Brookings Graduate School of Economics and Government (est. 1924).  Press, 2003); U.S. Government Accounting Office, "Federal-aid highways: Cost and oversight of major highway and bridge projects--issues and options," GAO-03-764T, Testimony before the Subcommittee on Transportation, Treasury and Independent Agencies, Committee on Appropriations, House of Representatives; Statement for the Record by JayEtta Z. Hecker, Director, Physical Infrastructure Issues (Washington, D.C., 2003); and the United Kingdom, National Audit Office, "PFI PFI Pay for Inclusion (web search engines)
PFI Private Finance Initiative
PFI Private Finance Initiative (UK)
PFI Prison Fellowship International
PFI Port Fuel Injection (engines) 
: construction performance," Report by the Comptroller and Auditor General Comptroller and Auditor General is the abbreviated title of a government official in a number of states, including the United Kingdom, the Republic of Ireland, India, and China.  (London: National Audit Office, 2003).

(16) Andre F. Perold, "The capital asset pricing model Capital asset pricing model (CAPM)

An economic theory that describes the relationship between risk and expected return, and serves as a model for the pricing of risky securities.
," Journal of Economic Perspectives 18, no. 3 (Summer 2004), pp. 3-24.

(17) See United Kingdom, National Audit Office, Examining the Value for Money of Deals under the Private Finance Initiative (London: National Audit Office, 1999); and United Kingdom, Her Majesty's Treasury, Public Private Partnerships--The Government's Approach (London: HMSO HMSO (in Britain) Her (or His) Majesty's Stationery Office

HMSO n abbr (BRIT) (= His (or Her) Majesty's Stationery Office) → distribuidor oficial de las publicaciones del gobierno del Reino Unido
, 2000).

(18) Oliver E. Williamson, Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications (New York New York, state, United States
New York, Middle Atlantic state of the United States. It is bordered by Vermont, Massachusetts, Connecticut, and the Atlantic Ocean (E), New Jersey and Pennsylvania (S), Lakes Erie and Ontario and the Canadian province of
: The Free Press, 1975).

(19) Steven Globerman and Aidan R. Vining, "A framework for evaluating the government contracting-out decision with an application to information technology," Public Administration Review 56, no. 6 (November/December 1996), pp. 40-6.

(20) See Leroy P. Jones, Pankaj Tandon and Ingo Vogelsang, Selling Public Enterprises: A Cost-Benefit Methodology (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT MIT - Massachusetts Institute of Technology  Press, 1990).

(21) Anthony E. Boardman and Erica Susan Hewitt, "Problems with contracting out government services: Lessons from orderly services at SCGH SCGH Sir Charles Gairdner Hospital (Australia) ," Industrial and Corporate Change 13, no. 6 (December 2004), pp. 917-29.

(22) Jean-Etienne de Bettignies and Thomas Ross, "The economics of public-private partnerships," Canadian Public Policy Canadian Public Policy is Canada's leading journal examining economic and social policy. The aim of the journal is to stimulate research and discussion of public policy problems in Canada.  30, no. 2 (June 2004), pp. 135-54. Governments cannot borrow extensively without affecting their credit rating: Raising funds for a P3 may raise the cost of borrowing for subsequent projects and should be included in the "full" cost of the P3.

(23) Dirk-Jan Kraan, Budgetary Decisions: A Public Choice Approach (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press Cambridge University Press (known colloquially as CUP) is a publisher given a Royal Charter by Henry VIII in 1534, and one of the two privileged presses (the other being Oxford University Press). , 1996), p. 2.

(24) Joseph Cordes, "Reconciling normative and positive theories of government," The American Economic Review 87, no. 2 (May 1997), p. 169.

(25) See Geert R. Teisman and Erik-Hans Klijn, "Partnership arrangements: Governmental rhetoric or governance scheme," Public Administration Review 62, no. 2 (March/April 2002), pp. 197-205; and Jeff W. Trailer, Paula Rechner and Robert C. Hill Robert Charles Hill (September 30, 1917 - November 28, 1978) was a United States diplomat who served as U.S. ambassador to several Latin American countries throughout his career. His last posting was in Argentina in the late 1970s, a period of great unrest in that country. , "A compound agency problem: An empirical examination of public-private partnerships," Journal of American Academy of Business, Cambridge 5, nos. 1/2 (September 2004), pp. 308-15.

(26) There is an extensive literature. See, for example, Anthony E. Boardman and Aidan R. Vining, "Ownership and performance in competitive environments: A comparison of the performance of private, mixed and state owned enterprises," Journal of Law and Economics 32, no. 1 (April 1989), pp. 1-34; and Toshiyuki Sueyoshi, "Privatization of Nippon Telegraph and Telephone Nippon Telegraph and Telephone Corporation (日本電信電話株式会社  : Was it a good policy decision?," European Journal of Operational Research 107, no. 1 (16 May 1998), pp. 45-61.

(27) Trevor Brown Though presently living in Japan, Trevor Brown is an English artist from London whose work explores paraphilias, such as pedophilia, BDSM, and other fetish themes.

Trevor Brown's art has been featured in Adam Parfrey's Apocalypse Culture II, and in Jim Goad's ANSWER Me!
 and Matthew Potoski, "Managing contract performance: A transaction cost approach," Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 22, no. 2 (Spring 2003), pp. 275-97.

(28) For evidence, see J. Michael Geringer and Louis Herbert, "Measuring performance of international joint ventures," Journal of International Business Studies JIBS, the Journal of International Business Studies, (ISSN: 0047-2506, eISSN: 1478-6990) is the official publication of the Academy of International Business (AIB) and is published by Palgrave Macmillan.  22, no. 2 (Fall 1991), pp. 249-63; and Andrew Inkpen and Paul W. Beamish, "Knowledge, bargaining power and international joint venture instability," Academy of Management Review 22, no. 1 (January 1997), pp. 177-202.

(29) Christine Brown Christine Brown is a politician and current municipal councillor in St. Albert, Alberta. She holds a Master's in Economics and teaches the subject at Grant MacEwan College.[1] She also runs an economic consultancy, CMB Consulting. , "Financing transport infrastructure: for whom the road tolls," The Australian Economic Review 38, no. 4 (December 2005), pp. 431-38.

(30) Martin Roll and Alain Verbeke, "Financing of the trans-European high-speed rail networks: New forms of public-private partnerships," European Management Journal 16, no. 6 (December 1998), pp. 706-13.

(31) R. Preston McAfee R. Preston McAfee (born July 7, 1956) is the J. Stanley Johnson Professor of Business, Economics, and Management at the California Institute of Technology, where he is the executive officer for the social sciences.  and John McMillan John McMillan may refer to:
  • John McMillan (economist) (1951–2007), Professor of Economics at Stanford University, University of California San Diego, and University of Western Ontario
, Incentives in Government Contracting (Toronto: University of Toronto Research at the University of Toronto has been responsible for the world's first electronic heart pacemaker, artificial larynx, single-lung transplant, nerve transplant, artificial pancreas, chemical laser, G-suit, the first practical electron microscope, the first cloning of T-cells,  Press, 1988).

(32) Ken Coghill and Dennis Woodward, "Political issues of private-private partnerships," in Hodge and Greve, eds., The Challenge of Public-Private Partnerships, pp. 81-94.

(33) For discussions of public choice in a Canadian context, see Douglas E. Hartle, The Expenditure Budget Process of the Government of Canada The Government of Canada is the federal government of Canada. The powers and structure of the federal government are set out in the Constitution of Canada.

In modern Canadian use, the term "government" (or "federal government") refers broadly to the cabinet of the day and
: A Public Choice-Rent-Seeking Perspective (Toronto: Canadian Tax Foundation The Canadian Tax Foundation is an independent tax research non-profit organization with over 8,000 individual and corporate members in Canada and abroad. For over 50 years, it has fostered a better understanding of the Canadian tax system, and assisted in the development of that , 1988); and Mark Sproule-Jones, "Institutions and constitutions: Public choices in Canada," in Laurent Dobuzinskis, Michael Howlett Michael J. Howlett (August 30, 1914 - May 4, 1992) served three terms as state of Illinois Auditor of Public Accounts (predecessor to the office of Comptroller) (1961-1973) and became Illinois Secretary of State in 1973, serving in that position until 1977.  and David Laycock, eds., Policy Studies in Canada: The State of the Art (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1996), pp. 149-69.

(34) See Williamson, Markets and Hierarchies; Globerman and Vining, "The government contracting out decision," Public Administration Review; and Broadbent, Gill and Laughlin, "The development of contracting in the context of infrastructure investment in the U.K.," International Public Management Journal.

(35) See Boardman and Hewitt, "Problems with contracting out government services," Industrial and Corporate Change.

(36) See Anthony E. Boardman, Finn Poschmann and Aidan R. Vining, "North American North American

named after North America.


North American blastomycosis
see North American blastomycosis.

North American cattle tick
see boophilusannulatus.
 infrastructure P3s: Examples and lessons learned," in Hodge and Greve, The Challenge of Public-Private Partnerships, pp. 162-89; and Vining, Boardman and Poschmann, "Public-private partnerships in the U.S. and Canada," Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis.

(37) Richard Sherbaniuk, "The price of protection," Alberta Views (Summer 1998), p. 26.

(38) Ibid., p. 30.

(39) See Jack Mintz, "An evaluation of the joint venture agreement establishing the Alberta Special Waste Management System" (Toronto: University of Toronto, Faculty of Management, 1995).

(40) Sherbaniuk, "The price of protection," Alberta Views, p. 32.

(41) BOVAR Inc., Annual Report 2000. Available at http://www.orbus.ca/reports/1.pdf.

(42) Mintz, "An evaluation of the joint venture agreement establishing the Alberta Special Waste Management System" [unpublished paper].

(43) Salim J. Loxley, "An analysis of a public private sector partnership: The Confederation Bridge." A report prepared for the Canadian Union of Public Employees The Canadian Union of Public Employees (CUPE, French: Syndicat canadien de la fonction publique) is a Canadian trade union serving the public sector - although it has in recent years organized workplaces in the non-profit and para-public sector as well. , 1999.

(44) See Receiver General for Canada The Receiver General for Canada (French: Receveur général du Canada) is responsible for making payments to the Canadian government each fiscal year, accepting payments from financial institutions and preparing the Public Accounts of Canada, containing annual audited , Public Accounts of Canada, 1995. Volume 1 (Ottawa: Canadian Government Publishing, 1995).

(45) Mylvaganam and Borins, If You Build It: Business, Government and Ontario's Electronic Highway.

(46) S.G. Hambros, Public-Private Partnerships for Highways: Experience, Structure, Financing, Applicability and Comparative Assessment. Objective One: Final Report. Report to the Council of Deputy Ministers Responsible for Transportation and Highway Safety (Ottawa: Transport Canada Transport Canada is the department within the government of Canada which is responsible for developing regulations, policies and services of transportation in Canada. History , 1999).

(47) Eugenio Mendoza This article or section needs sources or references that appear in reliable, third-party publications. Alone, primary sources and sources affiliated with the subject of this article are not sufficient for an accurate encyclopedia article. , Parmar Gold, Jodie Mitchell and Peter Carter, "'The sale of highway 407 express toll route: A case study," Journal of Project Finance 5, no. 3 (Fall 1999), pp. 5-14.

(48) Roy Hrab, "Privatization: Experience and prospects." Panel on the Role of Government in Ontario, University of Toronto, June 2003. Research Paper # 22, available at www.law-lib. utoronto/investing/about.htm.

(49) R. Mackie, "McGinty shrugs off highway toll spat," Globe and Mail (12 August 2004), p. A4..

(50) Steve Erwin, "Ontario settles with operators of highway 407 over toll rate controversy," Canadian Business Canadian Business is the longest-publishing business magazine in Canada. It was founded in 1928 as The Commerce of the Nation, the organ of the Canadian Chamber of Commerce. The magazine was renamed Canadian Business in 1933.  Online (2006).

(51) Ibid.

(52) Hambros, Public-Private Partnerships for Highways.

(53) Mylvaganam and Borins, If You Build It: Business, Government and Ontario's Electronic Highway.

(54) Julia Kuzeljevich, "Too heavy atoll," Motor Truck 71, no. 5 (September/October 2002), p. 18.

(55) Joan Price Boase, "Beyond government: The appeal of public-private partnerships," CANADIAN PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION 43, no. 1 (Spring 2000), pp. 75-92.

(56) Mylvaganam and Borins, If You Build It: Business, Government and Ontario's Electronic Highway.

(57) See Cobequid Pass Toll Highway: The BEST Example of how a Public/Private PARTNERSHIP should Work [web site] (Halifax: Highway 104 Western Alignment Corporation, 2004), available at www.highwayl04.ns.ca/index.htm.

(58) Canada, Canadian Rural Partnership: Rural Development, Public-Private Partnerships in Rural and Northern Canada Northern Canada is the vast northernmost region of Canada variously defined by geography and politics. Definitions and usage
Also referred to as the Canadian North or (locally) as the North
 Study, Final Report. Report prepared for the Rural Secretariat The Rural Secretariat is a focal point for the Government of Canada to work in partnership with Canadians in rural and remote areas to build strong, dynamic communities. Located in Agriculture and Agri-Food Canada, it: provides leadership and coordination for the Canadian Rural  Agriculture and Agri-Food Canada The Department of Agriculture and Agri-Food, also referred to as Agriculture and Agri-Food Canada (AAFC) (French: Agriculture et Agroalimentaire Canada), is the department of the government of Canada with responsibility for policies governing agriculture  (Ottawa: Public Works and Government Services Canada Public Works and Government Services Canada, also referred to as Department of Public Works and Government Services, is the department of the government of Canada with responsibility for the government's internal servicing and administration. , 2004), available at http://www.rural.gc.ca/ruralreports/partnerships_c_e. phtml.

(59) Nova Scotia, Department of Transportation and Public Works, "No toll increase for the Cobequid Pass," New Release, 7 December 2005 (Halifax: Queen's Printer, 2005), available at http://www.gov.ns.ca/news/details.asp?id=20051207004.

(60) Nova Scotia, Office of the Auditor General, "Highway 104 western alignment project," Report of the Auditor General: 1996 Highlights (Halifax: Office of the Auditor General, 1997), p. 127.

(61) n.a., "New premier wants to get rid of tolls on Nova Scotia highway [Highway 104]," Daily Commercial News and Construction Record 72, no. 155 (13 August, 1999), p. A1.

(62) Matthew Sylvain, "Nova Scotia boosts tolls on Cobequid," Trick News 21, no. 1 (2001), p. 1.

(63) Nova Scotia, Department of Transportation and Public Works, "No toll increase for the Cobequid Pass," New Release.

(64) For details, see New Brunswick, Office of the Auditor General, Special Report for the Public Accounts Committee: Evergreen and Wackenhut Leases (Fredericton: Office of the Auditor General of New Brunswick, 1998); and New Brunswick, Office of the Auditor General, Annual Report, 1998 (Fredericton: Office of the Auditor General of New Brunswick, 1998).

(65) Salim J. Loxley, "An analysis of a public-private sector partnership: The Evergreen Park School, Moncton, N.B." Unpublished report prepared for the Canadian Union of Public Employees, 1999, p. 9.

(66) Ibid.

(67) Sylvia Fuller, ed., Assessing the Record of Public-Private Partnerships. Proceedings of a CCPA-BC Public Forum (Vancouver: Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives The Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives is a union-supported left-wing policy research institute in Canada. It concentrates on economic policy, international trade, and social policy. It is especially known for publishing an alternative federal budget on an annual basis. , 2003).

(68) New Brunswick, Office of the Auditor General, Annual Report, 1998.

(69) Ibid., p. 187.

(70) Ibid., p. 189.

(71) Ibid.

(72) Michael Trottier and Jeffrey Maguire, "Case studies," Public Policy Report No. 4 (Saskatoon Saskatoon (săskətn`), city (1991 pop. 186,058), S central Sask., Canada, on the South Saskatchewan River. : Saskatchewan Institute of Public Policy, 2001), available at www.uregina.ca/sipp/ documents/pdf/casestudies.pdf.

(73) Ibid., p. 51.

(74) Ibid., p. 52.

(75) Canadian Council Canadian Council may refer to:

In aviation:
  • Canadian Airports Council, the Canadian trade association for Canada's airports
  • Canadian Aviation Regulation Advisory Council, a public consultative body involved in creating the Canadian Aviation Regulations
 for Public-Private Partnerships, 100 Projects: Selected Public-Private Partnerships across Canada--2000 Edition (Toronto: Canadian Council for Public-Private Partnerships, 2001).

(76) Nova Scotia, Office of the Auditor General, Auditor General--O'Connell Drive Elementary School Lease. Press Release. 23 July 1998 (Halifax: Office of the Auditor General of Nova Scotia, 1998).

(77) Trottier and Maguire, "Case studies," Public Policy Report No. 4.

(78) Nova Scotia, Office of the Auditor General, Auditor General--O'Connell Drive Elementary School Lease. Press Release.

(79) Heather-Jane Robertson, "Why P3 schools are D4 schools or how private-public-partnerships lead to disillusionment Disillusionment
Adams, Nick

loses innocence through WWI experience. [Am. Lit.: “The Killers”]

Angry Young Men

disillusioned postwar writers of Britain, such as Osborne and Amis. [Br. Lit.
, dirty dealings and debt," in Fuller, Assessing the Record of Public-Private Partnerships, pp. 8-13.

(80) Heather-Jane Robertson, "Incent in·cent  
tr.v. in·cent·ed, in·cent·ing, in·cents
To incentivize: "would use tax breaks to incent corporations to invest in their future" Scott Canon.
 this!," Phi Delta Kappan 84, no. 9 (May, 2003), pp. 713-14.

(81) Nova Scotia, Office of the Auditor General, Auditor General--O'Connell Drive Elementary School Lease. Press Release.

(82) Ibid.

(83) See EPCOR, "Britannia Mine Water Treatment Plant," Epcor [web site] ([Edmonton]: Epcor Utilities Inc., [2007]), available at www.epcor.com/communities/BCPNW/Operations/ WaterandWastewater/britanniamine.

(84) British Columbia, Partnerships BC and Ministry of Sustainable Resource Management, Project Report: Achieving Value for Money--Britannia Mine Water Treatment Plant (Victoria: Queen's Printer, 2005), available at http://www.partnershipsbc.ca/pdf/Britannia_Value for Money_Report_March_05_FINAL.pdf.

(85) Ibid.

(86) See EPCOR, "Britannia Mine Water Treatment Plant," Epcor [web site].

(87) British Columbia, Partnerships BC and Ministry of Sustainable Resource Management, Project Report: Achieving Value for Money--Britannia Mine Water Treatment Plant.

(88) Ibid.

(89) Elizabeth Brubaker, "Public Goals, Private Means: Why the Private Sector is Uniquely Capable of Providing Water and Wastewater Services to Ontario's Municipalities." Paper presented at Public Goals, Private Means Research Colloquium Noun 1. research colloquium - a colloquium at which the results of (scientific) research are reported
colloquium - an academic meeting or seminar usually led by a different lecturer and on a different topic at each meeting
, University of Toronto, Faculty of Law, October, 2003, p. 3.

(90) Elizabeth Brubaker, "Lessons from Walkerton," Fraser Forum (April 2002), pp. 12-15.

(91) Canadian Union of Public Employees, CUPE Locals 34, 1948, 2268 and 3730, "Public Risk, Private Profit: Why Lease Back Schools are Bad for K-12 Education." Brief to the Saskatoon Catholic and Public School Board (Ottawa: CUPE, 2001), available at http://cupe.ca/www/ SchoolBaords/4291.

(92) City of Moncton, City Hall, Moncton/Riverview/Dieppe. 2002 Annual Water Quality Report. Moncton Water Treatment Plant (Moncton: City of Moncton, 2002), available at http://www. moncton.org/search/english/CITYHALL/water/2002%20Annual%20Water%20Quality%20 Report.pdf.

(93) After winning the contract, USF offered to manage the entire water distribution system. The union raised strong opposition to the deal, and provincial officials argued the project violated the Public Purchasing Act, which requires municipalities to issue RFPs for major infrastructure projects. In March 2002, city council rejected the offer.

(94) Canada, Canadian Rural Partnership: Rural Development, Public-Private Partnerships in Rural and Northern Canada Study, Final Report.

(95) Canadian Union of Public Employees, In the Public lnterest: Keeping Water in Public Hands.

Presentation to the North Battleford North Battleford, city (1991 pop. 14,350), W Sask., Canada, at the confluence of the North Saskatchewan and Battle rivers, opposite Battleford. It is the service and distribution center for NW Saskatchewan, which has rich farming, lumbering, and fishing.  City Council by Canadian Union of Public Employees Local 287 (Ottawa: CUPE, 2002), available at http://www.cupe.ca/privatization/ nbattlefordwaterp3.

(96) Canada, Canadian Rural Partnership: Rural Development, Public-Private Partnerships in Rural and Northern Canada Study, Final Report.

(97) Canadian Union of Public Employees, In the Public Interest: Keeping Water in Public Hands.

(98) Canada, Canadian Rural Partnership: Rural Development, Public-Private Partnerships in Rural and Northern Canada Study, Final Report.

(99) Canadian Union of Public Employees, In the Public Interest: Keeping Water in Public Hands.

(100) Barry Clouter, "1999 rears its head: Our failed public private adventure," Cranbrook Daily Townsman (2004), p. 4.

(101) Conestoga-Rovers & Associates, Handbook for the Preparation of Landfill Gas to Energy Projects in Latin America Latin America, the Spanish-speaking, Portuguese-speaking, and French-speaking countries (except Canada) of North America, South America, Central America, and the West Indies.  and the Caribbean. Prepared for World Bank Energy Sector Management Assistance Program (ESMAP ESMAP Energy Sector Management Assistance Programme (World Bank) ) (Waterloo, Ont.: Conestoga-Rovers & Associates, 2004), Box 4, pp. 70-71, available at http://www.bvsde.paho.org/bvsacd/cd51/preparation/part2.pdf.

(102) Conestoga-Rovers & Associates, "Case Study: Region of Waterloo LFGTE LFGTE Landfill Gas To Energy  Project" Unpublished report, 2003.

(103) Ibid.

(104) Ibid.

(105) See Vining, Boardman and Poschmann, "Public-private partnerships in the U.S. and Canada," Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis.

(106) D. Asenova and M. Beck, "The U.K. financial sector and risk management in PFI projects: A survey," Public Money and Management 23, no. 3 (July 2003), pp. 195-203; Pamela Edwards and Jean Shaoul, "Partnerships: For better or worse," Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal 16, no. 3 (March 2003), pp. 397-421.

(107) Linda M. English and James Guthrie James Guthrie may refer to:
  • James Guthrie (American politician) (1792–1869) an American businessman and politician
  • James Guthrie (artist) (1859–1930)
  • James Guthrie (record producer)
  • James Guthrie (divine) (1612-1661) Scottish presbyterian divine
, "Driving privately financed projects in Australia: What makes them tick?," Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal 16, no. 3 (March 2003), pp. 493-511.

(108) B. Li, "Risk management of public/private partnership projects" (Ph.D. diss diss  
v.
Variant of dis.


diss
Verb

Slang, chiefly US to treat (a person) with contempt [from disrespect]

Verb 1.
., School of the Built and Natural Environment, Glasgow Caledonian University Glasgow Caledonian University is a university in Glasgow, Scotland.

Glasgow Caledonian began in 1875 as a small college with 110 students. Since then it has grown and diversified into one of the largest universities in Scotland with over 15,000 students as of 2004.
, 2003).

=====
Table 1. Major Canadian P3 Projects

                           Start         Term
Project                     year       (years)       Design

Abbotsford Regional         2004          30           Y
Hospital and Cancer
Centre

Aurora College Family       2000          20           Y
Student Housing

Brampton Centre for         1997          34           Y
Sports & Entertainment
(PowerAde Centre)

Britannia Mine Water        2005          21           Y
Treatment Plant

Centracare Psychiatric      1997          25
Care Facility

Charleswood Bridge          1995          30           Y

Highway 104 Western         1997          30           Y
Alignment Project
(Cobequid Pass)

Confederation Bridge        1997          30           Y

Cranbrook Civic Arena       1999          30           Y
Multiplex

Evergreen Park School       1995          25           Y

Goderich Harbour            1996          15
Revitalization

Guelph Sports &             1998          35           Y
Entertainment Complex

Halifax Harbour             2004          30           Y
Solutions

Hamilton- Wentworth         1999          5            Y
Water & Wastewater

Highway 407 ETR             1999          99           Y

Moncton Water               2005          20           Y
Treatment Facility

O'Connell Drive             1994          35           Y
Elementary School

Ottawa Superdome            2003          25           Y

RAV Line/Canada Line        2005          35           Y

Royal Ottawa Hospital       2004          23           Y

Sarnia Sports and           1997          20           Y
Entertainment Facility

The Secure Channel          2001          5            Y

Toronto Union Station       2003         100           Y
Revitalization

Waterloo Landfill Gas       1998          22           Y
Power Plant

William Osler Health        2001          25           Y
Centre

                           Build/
                            Buy/
Project                    Lease       Operate      Finance

Abbotsford Regional          Y            Y            Y
Hospital and Cancer
Centre

Aurora College Family        Y            Y            Y
Student Housing

Brampton Centre for          Y            Y            Y
Sports & Entertainment
(PowerAde Centre)

Britannia Mine Water         Y            Y            Y
Treatment Plant

Centracare Psychiatric       Y            Y            Y
Care Facility

Charleswood Bridge           Y            Y            Y

Highway 104 Western          Y            Y            Y
Alignment Project
(Cobequid Pass)

Confederation Bridge         Y            Y            Y

Cranbrook Civic Arena        Y            Y            Y
Multiplex

Evergreen Park School        Y            Y            Y

Goderich Harbour             Y            Y            Y
Revitalization

Guelph Sports &              Y            Y            Y
Entertainment Complex

Halifax Harbour              Y            Y            Y
Solutions

Hamilton- Wentworth          Y            Y            Y
Water & Wastewater

Highway 407 ETR            Lease          Y            Y

Moncton Water                Y            Y            Y
Treatment Facility

O'Connell Drive              Y            Y            Y
Elementary School

Ottawa Superdome             Y            Y            Y
                                                    (Shared)

RAV Line/Canada Line         Y            Y            Y

Royal Ottawa Hospital        Y            Y            Y

Sarnia Sports and            Y            Y            Y
Entertainment Facility

The Secure Channel           Y            Y            Y

Toronto Union Station     Restore         Y            Y
Revitalization

Waterloo Landfill Gas        Y            Y            Y
Power Plant

William Osler Health         Y            Y            Y
Centre
Revitalization

Waterloo Landfill Gas        Y            Y            Y
Power Plant

William Osler Health         Y            Y            Y
Centre

                         Contract
Project                  size         Public Partner

Abbotsford Regional      $355 mil-    Ministry of
Hospital and Cancer      lion plus    Health, Fraser
Centre                   $40.6 mil-   Health,
                         lion/year    Provincial
                                      Health
                                      Services, BC
                                      Cancer Agency,
                                      Fraser Valley
                                      Regional
                                      Hospital,
                                      Partnerships
                                      BC

Aurora College Family    $4.70        NWT Provincial
Student Housing          million      Government
                         plus
                         $745,000/
                         year

Brampton Centre for      $26.5 mil-   City of
Sports & Entertain-      lion plus    Brampton
ment (PowerAde           $230,000/
Centre)                  year

Britannia Mine Water     $27.2 mil-   Province of
Treatment Plant          lion         British
                                      Columbia

Centracare Psychiatric   $6.50        Province of New
Care Facility            million      Brunswick

Charleswood Bridge       $15          City of
                         million

Highway 104 Western      $113         Winnipeg
Alignment Project        million      Province of
(Cobequid Pass)                       Nova Scotia

Confederation Bridge     $730 mil-    Government of
                         lion         Canada

Cranbrook Civic Arena    $22.6 mil-   City of
Multiplex                lion plus    Cranbrook
                         $801,000/
                         year

Evergreen Park School    $14.8 mil-   Province of New
                         lion         Brunswick

Goderich Harbour         $650,000     Town of
Revitalization           plus $1.4    Goderich
                         million an-
                         nual trust
                         fund

Guelph Sports & Enter-   $21          City of Guelph
tainment Complex         million

Halifax Harbour          $133 mil-    Government of
Solutions                lion         Canada,
                                      Province of
                                      Nova Scotia

Hamilton- Wentworth      $7.5         City of
Water & Wastewater       million      Hamilton

Highway 407 ETR          $3.1         Province of
                         billion      Ontario

Moncton Water Treat-     $85          City of Moncton
ment Facility            million

O'Connell Drive          $8 million   Province of
Elementary School        plus         Nova Scotia
                         $59,000/
                         month

Ottawa Superdome         $3.5         City of Ottawa
                         million

RAV Line/Canada Line     $1.8         Greater
                         billion      Vancouver
                                      Transportation
                                      Authority,
                                      Govt. of
                                      Canada,
                                      Province of
                                      BC, YVRAA

Royal Ottawa Hospital    $120 mil-    Province of
                         lion         Ontario

Sarnia Sports and        $15.9 mil-   City of Sarnia
Entertainment Facility   lion

The Secure Channel       $57          Government of
                         million      Canada

Toronto Union Station    $5 million   City of Toronto
Revitalization

Waterloo Landfill Gas    $7.5         Regional
Power Plant              million      Municipality
                                      of Waterloo

William Osler Health     $550 mil-    Province of
Centre                   lion         Ontario

Project                  Private Partner

Abbotsford Regional      Access Health
Hospital and Cancer      Abbotsford Ltd.
Centre

Aurora College Family    Aurora Building
Student Housing          Developers

Brampton Centre for      Realstar &
Sports & Entertain-      Edilcan Groups
ment (PowerAde           (Brampton
Centre)                  Sports Centre
                         Inc.)

Britannia Mine Water     EPCOR Water
Treatment Plant          Services

Centracare Psychiatric   Pomerleau Inc.
Care Facility            & Cardinal
                         Construction
                         Inc.

Charleswood Bridge       DBF Ltd.

Highway 104 Western      Highway 104
Alignment Project        Western
(Cobequid Pass)          Alignment
                         Corporation

Confederation Bridge     Strait Crossing
                         Development

Cranbrook Civic Arena    Inc. Vestar
Multiplex                Inc.

Evergreen Park School    Greenarm
                         Corporation

Goderich Harbour         Sifto Canada
Revitalization           Ltd.

Guelph Sports & Enter-   Nustadia
tainment Complex         Developments
                         (Recreation)
                         Inc.

Halifax Harbour          Harbour
Solutions                Solutions
                         Consortium

Hamilton- Wentworth      Azurix
Water & Wastewater

Highway 407 ETR          407
                         International
                         Inc.

Moncton Water Treat-     USFilter
ment Facility            Canada

O'Connell Drive          Nova Learning
Elementary School        Inc.

Ottawa Superdome         Thunderbird
                         Mgmt. Services
                         Inc.

RAV Line/Canada Line     Intransit BC

Royal Ottawa Hospital    The Healthcare
                         Infrastructure
                         Company of
                         Canada

Sarnia Sports and        Nustadia
Entertainment Facility   Developments
                         Inc.

The Secure Channel       Team BCE

Toronto Union Station    The Union
Revitalization           Pearson Group
                         Inc.

Waterloo Landfill Gas    Toromont Energy
Power Plant

William Osler Health     The Healthcare
Centre                   Infrastructure
                         Company of
                         Canada

Table 2. Key Factors in Assessing P3 Case Studies

                       Asset           Construction    Cost risk
Project P3             specificity     complexity      transferred

Alberta Special        Yes             Moderate        Partially
Waste Management
System
Confederation          Yes             Moderate        Yes
Bridge

Highway 407            Yes             Moderate        Yes
ETR
Highway 104            Yes             Moderate        Yes

Evergreen Park         Yes             Low             Yes
School
O'Connell Drive        Yes             Low             Yes, but
Elementary                                             costs high
School
Britannia Mine         Yes             Moderate        Yes
Water Treatment
Plant
Moncton Water          Yes             Moderate        Yes
Treatment Facility
Cranbrook Civic        Yes             Low             No, in
Arena Multiplex                                        effect
Waterloo Landfill      Yes             Low             Yes
Gas Power
Plant

                       Use-                            Gov. contract
                       (revenue)       Use-risk        management
Project P3             uncertainty     transferred     skills

Alberta Special        Moderate        Not for first   Poor
Waste Management                       ten years
System
Confederation          High            Small           Fair
Bridge                                 (revenue
                                       guarantees)

Highway 407            High            No              Poor
ETR
Highway 104            High-           No              Fair
                       Moderate

Evergreen Park         Low             Yes             Fair
School
O'Connell Drive        Low             No              Poor
Elementary
School
Britannia Mine         Moderate        Yes             Good
Water Treatment
Plant
Moncton Water          Low             Partially       Good
Treatment Facility
Cranbrook Civic        Moderate        Partially       Fair-Poor
Arena Multiplex
Waterloo Landfill      Low             Yes             Good
Gas Power
Plant

                       Externalities
                       or other
                       negative        Transaction
Project P3             events          costs           Success

Alberta Special        Yes             High            No
Waste Management
System
Confederation                          Moderate        Qualified
Bridge                                                 Yes

Highway 407            Yes             High            No
ETR
Highway 104            Toll-level      Moderate        Qualified
                       problems                        No

Evergreen Park                         Moderate        Yes
School
O'Connell Drive        High            High            No
Elementary
School
Britannia Mine                         Low             Yes
Water Treatment
Plant
Moncton Water                          Low             Yes
Treatment Facility
Cranbrook Civic                        High            No
Arena Multiplex
Waterloo Landfill                      Average         Yes
Gas Power
Plant


Aidan Vining is CNABS Professor of Government and Business Relations, Faculty of Business Administration, Simon Fraser University Simon Fraser University, main campus at Burnaby, British Columbia, Canada; provincially supported; coeducational; chartered 1963, opened 1965. The Harbour Centre campus in downtown Vancouver opened in 1989. , Vancouver. Anthony Boardman is the Van Dusen Professor of Business Administration, Strategy and Business Economics Division, Sauder School of Business The Sauder School of Business is a business school at the University of British Columbia located in the University Endowment Lands, just west of the city limits of Vancouver, Canada, which provides diploma, bachelor, masters and Ph.D. programs. , University of British Columbia Locations
Vancouver
The Vancouver campus is located at Point Grey, a twenty-minute drive from downtown Vancouver. It is near several beaches and has views of the North Shore mountains. The 7.
. The authors thank Michelle Barnes for excellent research assistance and Mark Moore for helpful comments and suggestions. They would also like to acknowledge support from the UBC P3 Project and Infrastructure Canada Infrastructure Canada is part of the Transport, Infrastructure and Communities portfolio of the Government of Canada. Established in August 2002, the organization was formerly associated with Treasury Board Secretariat, the Privy Council Office, Industry Canada, and Environment  under the Knowledge-Building, Outreach and Awareness Program. Earlier versions of this article were presented at the Canadian Political Science Annual Meeting, Toronto, 1-3 June 2006, and at the UBC P3 Academic Workshop, Vancouver, 6 December 2006. Finally, they thank the Journal's anonymous reviewers for their suggestions.
COPYRIGHT 2008 Institute of Public Administration of Canada
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2008 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.

 Reader Opinion

Title:

Comment:



 

Article Details
Printer friendly Cite/link Email Feedback
Author:Vining, Aidan R.; Boardman, Anthony E.
Publication:Canadian Public Administration
Geographic Code:1CANA
Date:Mar 1, 2008
Words:15031
Previous Article:Editor's introduction to the special issue on public-private partnerships/Introduction par la redactrice du numero special sur les partenariats...
Next Article:Commercializing air traffic control: have the reforms worked?
Topics:



Related Articles
The Job of Public Sector Managers is to Maximise Public Value.
Strong communities: the importance of building partnerships.
The case for public-private partnerships in infrastructure.
Combining resources: public-private partnerships emerge as an innovative transportation financing tool.

Terms of use | Copyright © 2014 Farlex, Inc. | Feedback | For webmasters