Printer Friendly

Monetary policy in the 2008-2009 recession.

Powerful real shocks combined to buffet the economy in 2007 and 2008. A combination of a fall in housing wealth from declining house prices and a fall in real income from increasing energy and food prices made individuals worse off. Although a moderate recession began at the end of 2007, it intensified in the summer of 2008. Based on the view that dysfunction in credit markets intensified the recession, monetary policy has focused on intervention into individual credit markets deemed impaired.

The alternative explanation offered here for the intensification of the recession emphasizes propagation of the original real shocks through contractionary monetary policy Contractionary monetary policy is monetary policy that seeks to reduce the size of the money supply. In most nations, monetary policy is controlled by either a central bank or a finance ministry. . The intensification of the recession followed the pattern of recessions in the stop-go period of the late 1960s and 1970s, in which the Fed introduced cyclical inertia in the funds relative to changes in economic activity, For example, in late 1973 and early 1974, an inflation shock because of an oil-price rise and the end of price controls reduced real income. The recession that began in November 1973 intensified in the late fall of 1974. In the summer of 1974, the Fed backed away from its procedures calling for reductions in the funds rate in response to deteriorating economic activity (Hetzel 2008a, Ch. 10). However, with a funds rate that peaked in July 1974 at 13 percent, the Fed eventually had ample room to lower significantly the nominal and real funds rate. What is unusual about the current period is the zero-lower-bound (ZLB ZLB Zero Length Body
ZLB Zero Length Bit
) constraint that arises with a zero-funds rate.

The argument advanced here is that in the summer of 2008 the Federal Open Market Committee's (FOMC See Federal Open Market Committee.

FOMC

See Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC).
) departure from its standard procedures calling for reductions in the funds rate in response to deteriorating economic activity produced a monetary shock that exacerbated the recession. Such an argument involves a "what if?" counterfactual about policy. The complexity of forces affecting economic activity renders the validity of policy counterfactuals for individual episodes uncertain. Nevertheless, the explanation advanced here for the intensification of the recession falls into a longer-run pattern of recessions. The spirit of this article is to use empirical generalizations deduced from historical experience and constrained by theory so that they are robust for predicting the consequences of monetary policy. The two contenders matched here are the credit-cycle view and the quantity-theory view of cyclical fluctuations. The credit-cycle view explains cyclical movements in output as a consequence of speculative booms leading to unsustainable levels of asset prices and leveraged levels of asset holdings followed by credit busts that depress economic activity through the impairment caused to the functioning of financial intermediation from insolvencies and deleveraging. The quantity-theory view explains significant cyclical movements in output as a consequence of monetary disorder deriving from the introduction by central banks This is a list of central banks.

Contents A B C D E F G H I J K L M N O P Q R S T U V W Y Z
 of inertia in adjustment of the interest rate to shocks.

Section 1 summarizes these two alternative frameworks for understanding cyclical fluctuations. Section 2 provides an intuitive overview of the quantity-theory framework. Section 3 provides an empirical characterization of the evolution of monetary policy, which relates that evolution to the degree of cyclical instability in the economy. Using this empirical generalization. Section 4 argues that monetary policy became contractionary in the summer of 2008. Section 5 makes normative recommendations for monetary policy faced with the ZLB constraint and argues for the creation of institutional arrangements that replace discretion with rules. Section 6 argues that, for a productive debate on institutional arrangements to occur between academic economists and policymakers, the latter will have to use the language of economics. An appendix, "Lessons from the Depression," uses the Depression as a laboratory for distinguishing between the efficacy of credit-channel and money-creation policies.

1. WHAT IS THE RIGHT FRAMEWORK FOR THINKING ABOUT MONETARY POLICY?

Very broadly, I place explanations of cyclical fluctuations in economic activity into two categories. The first category comprises explanations in which real forces overwhelm the working of the price system. According to according to
prep.
1. As stated or indicated by; on the authority of: according to historians.

2. In keeping with: according to instructions.

3.
 the credit cycle, or "psychological factors," explanation of the business cycle, waves of optimism arise and then inevitably give way to waves of pessimism. These swings in the psychology of investors overwhelm the stabilizing behavior of the price system. "High" interest rates fail to restrain speculative excess while "low" interest rates fail to offset the depressing effects of the liquidation The collection of assets belonging to a debtor to be applied to the discharge of his or her outstanding debts.

A type of proceeding pursuant to federal Bankruptcy
 of bad debt. In the real-bills variant, central banks initiate the phase driven by investor optimism through "cheap" credit (Hetzel 2008a, 12-3 and 34). Speculation in the boom phase drives both asset prices and leveraging through debt to unsustainable levels. The inevitable correction requires a period of deflation and recession to eliminate the prior speculative excesses. At present, this view appears in the belief that Wall Street bankers driven by greed took excessive risks and, in reaction, became excessively risk-averse (Hetzel 2009b).

Within this tradition, Keynesianism emerged in response to the pessimistic implication of real bills about the necessity of recession and deflation as foreordained fore·or·dain  
tr.v. fore·or·dained, fore·or·dain·ing, fore·or·dains
To determine or appoint beforehand; predestine.



fore
 because of the required liquidation of the excessive debts incurred in the boom period. As with psychological-factors explanations of the business cycle, investor "animal spirits animal spirits
pl.n.
The vitality of good health.


animal spirits
Noun, pl

outgoing and boisterous enthusiasm [from a vital force once supposed to be dispatched by the brain to all points of the body]
" drove the cycle. The failure of the price system to allocate resources efficiently, either across markets or over time, produced an underemployment equilibrium In Keynesian economics, underemployment equilibrium refers to a situation with a persistent shortfall relative to full employment and potential output so that unemployment is higher than at the NAIRU or the "natural" rate of unemployment.  in which, in response to shocks, real output adjusted, not prices. In a way given by the multiplier, real output would adjust to the variations in investment driven by animal spirits. The Keynesian model rationalized the policy prescription that, in recession, government deficit spending Deficit spending

When government spending overwhelms government revenue resulting in government borrowing.


deficit spending

Expenditures that are in excess of revenues during a given period of time.
 (amplified by the multiplier) should make up for the difference between the full employment and actual spending of the public. Monetary policy became impotent because banks and the public would simply hold on to the money balances created from central bank open market purchases (a liquidity trap Liquidity Trap

A situation in which prevailing interest rates are low and savings rates are high. As a result, monetary policy is ineffective.

Notes:
In a liquidity trap, consumers choose to avoid bonds and keep their funds in savings because of the prevailing belief that
).

Another variant of the view that periodically powerful real forces overwhelm the stabilizing properties of the price system is that imbalances create overproduction o·ver·pro·duce  
tr.v. o·ver·pro·duced, o·ver·pro·duc·ing, o·ver·pro·duc·es
To produce in excess of need or demand.



o
 in particular sectors because of entrepreneurial miscalculation mis·cal·cu·late  
tr. & intr.v. mis·cal·cu·lat·ed, mis·cal·cu·lat·ing, mis·cal·cu·lates
To count or estimate incorrectly.



mis·cal
. When these mistakes reinforce each other, an inventory correction inevitably occurs. Recession lasts until the correction of the prior imbalances has occurred. Monetary policy possesses only limited ability to offset the resulting swings in output.

At present, the real-bills variant of the psychological-factors view of cyclical instability explains the focus of monetary policy on subsidizing intermediation in financial markets judged dysfunctional. According to this view, financial market dysfunction because of prior speculative excess manifests itself in the apparent failure of investors to arbitrage disparate returns across markets and the apparent failure of banks to arbitrage the marginal cost Marginal cost

The increase or decrease in a firm's total cost of production as a result of changing production by one unit.


marginal cost

The additional cost needed to produce or purchase one more unit of a good or service.
 of borrowing and the marginal return to lending. Contrary to the pessimistic real-bills view that a period of recession and deflation must inevitably accompany correction of the prior excesses of a speculative bubble Speculative Bubble

A temporary market condition created through excessive buying, and an unfounded run-up in prices occurs.

Notes:
Speculative bubbles are generally a result of the "bandwagon effect.
 and analogous to the Keynesian critique of real bills, the assumption of policymakers is that government can shorten the adjustment period by taking losses off the private balance sheets of banks, for example, by recapitalizing banks. Also, central banks can directly replace the intermediation formerly provided by the private market.

Accordingly, after the FOMC's reduction of the funds rate to near zero in December 2008, many policymakers began to characterize monetary policy in terms of financial intermediation, that is, in terms of the Fed's purchases of debt in particular credit markets and how those purchases affect the cost of credit. The premise for this credit-channel view of the transmission of monetary policy is the existence of frictions in financial markets accompanied by negative externalities externalities

side-effects, either harmful or beneficial, borne by those not directly involved in the production of a commodity.
, which the central bank can mitigate by taking risky debt into its own portfolio. At the same time, in the spirit of the Keynesian liquidity trap, with a near-zero-funds rate, the resulting behavior of the monetary base (currency held by the public and commercial bank deposits at the Fed) possesses no implications for aggregate demand because banks and the public are operating on a flat section of their demand schedules where the monetary base and the debt acquired through open market operations Open Market Operations

The buying and selling of government securities in the open market in order to expand or contract the amount of money in the banking system. Purchases inject money into the banking system and stimulate growth while sales of securities do the opposite.
 are perfect substitutes.

In the second class of explanations of cyclical fluctuations, the price system generally works well to maintain output at its full employment level. In the real-business-cycle tradition, the price system works well without exception. In the quantity-theory tradition, it does so apart from episodes of monetary disorder that prevent the price system from offsetting cyclical fluctuations. Milton Friedman Noun 1. Milton Friedman - United States economist noted as a proponent of monetarism and for his opposition to government intervention in the economy (born in 1912)
Friedman
 (1960, 9) exposited the latter tradition:
  The Great Depression did much to instill and reinforce the now widely
  held view that inherent instability of a private market economy has
  been responsible for the major periods of economic distress
  experienced by the United States. ... As I read the historical
  record, I draw almost the opposite conclusion. In almost every
  instance, major instability in the United States has been produced
  or, at the very least, greatly intensified by monetary
  instability.


An implication of the quantity-theory view that the price system works efficiently to allocate resources is that investors arbitrage risk-adjusted yield differences among financial markets. While the frictions that operate in financial markets may become a greater impediment to intermediation in recession, these frictions derive from the general environment of economic uncertainty. There is little the central bank can do with credit market interventions apart from rearranging risk premia among different markets. In December 2008, the relevant friction was with the existence of money that created a ZLB constraint on the level of the interest rate. Even with a zero-funds rate, given the expectation of low inflation, the real interest rate, which becomes the negative of expected inflation, may be too high to offset the pessimism of individuals about their future income prospects. Nevertheless, through the creation of reserves resulting from the aggressive purchase of illiquid Illiquid

An asset or security that cannot be converted into cash very quickly (or near prevailing market prices).

Notes:
A house is a good example of an illiquid asset.
See also: Cash, Liquidity



Illiquid

In the context of finance.
 assets, the central bank can push banks and the public out of the flat section of their money demand schedules and stimulate asset acquisition and expenditure through portfolio rebalancing Rebalancing

The process of realigning the weightings of one's portfolio of assets.

Notes:
For example, if your portfolio's proportion of stock has grown too large for your intended assets weightings and risk tolerance, you might rebalance by selling some stock and putting
 by the public. (1)

Attribution of a particular recession to one of these two broad categories is inevitably problematic because of the large number of special factors at work. The claim made here is that the current recession adds one observation favorable to the quantity-theory or monetary-shock explanation of the business cycle. Whether readers find that explanation convincing will depend upon whether they interpret the long-run historical record as supporting this view.

The debate is perennial and appears in interpretation of the monetary transmission process going from central bank actions to the spending of the public. Should one understand it from the perspective of the ability of the central bank to influence conditions in credit markets or from the perspective of central bank control over money creation? John Maynard Keynes Noun 1. John Maynard Keynes - English economist who advocated the use of government monetary and fiscal policy to maintain full employment without inflation (1883-1946)
Keynes
 ([1930] 1971. 191) highlighted the two views:
  A banker ... is acting both as provider of money for his depositors,
  and also as a provider of resources for his borrowing-customers. Thus
  the modern banker performs two distinct sets of services. He supplies
  a substitute for State Money by acting as a clearing-house and
  transferring current payments. ... But he is also acting as a
  middleman in respect of a particular type of lending, receiving
  deposits from the public which he employs in purchasing securities,
  or in making loans. ... This duality of function is the clue to many
  difficulties in the modern Theory of Money and Credit and the source
  of some serious confusions of thought.


2. A HEURISTIC A method of problem solving using exploration and trial and error methods. Heuristic program design provides a framework for solving the problem in contrast with a fixed set of rules (algorithmic) that cannot vary.

1.
 DISCUSSION OF A QUANTITY THEORY FRAMEWORK

The quantity theory guides the formulation of empirical generalizations deduced from historical experience and constrained by theory so that they are robust for predicting the consequences of monetary policy. The heart of the quantity theory is the nominal/real distinction that derives from the assumption that individual welfare depends only upon real variables (physical quantities and relative prices). It follows that in a world with fiat money fiat money (fī`ət, fī`ăt), inconvertible money that is made legal tender by the decree, or fiat, of the government but that is not covered by a specie reserve.  central banks have to give nominal (dollar-denominated) variables well-defined values. Beyond this fundamental implication, Friedman used the nominal/real distinction to give the quantity theory empirical content through two empirical generalizations. First, Friedman ([1963] 1968, 39) argued that inflation is "always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon." Specifically, the rate of inflation depends positively upon the rate of money growth. Second, Friedman ([1963] 1968, 34-5; [1968] 1969) argued that, while unexpected inflation can stimulate output, expected inflation cannot. That is, the central bank cannot exercise systematic or predictable control over real variables (the natural-rate hypothesis). Nevertheless, monetary instability, which Friedman measured using fluctuations in the money stock relative to steady growth, destabilizes real output.

These empirical generalizations require reformulation for the world of unstable money demand that prevailed in the United States United States, officially United States of America, republic (2005 est. pop. 295,734,000), 3,539,227 sq mi (9,166,598 sq km), North America. The United States is the world's third largest country in population and the fourth largest country in area.  after 1980 (Hetzel 2004, 2005, 2006, 2008a, 2008b). The first generalization appears in the assumption that central banks determine trend inflation through their (explicit or implicit) inflation targets. The "monetary" character of inflation, which entails denial of exogenously given powerful cost-push forces that raise prices, implies that central banks can achieve their target for trend inflation without periodic recourse to "high" unemployment. The second generalization appears in the assumption that monetary stability requires that the central bank possess consistent procedures (a rule) that both allow the price system to work and that provide a nominal anchor (give the price level a well-defined value). As explained in Section 3, I characterize these procedures as "lean against the wind with credibility." Furthermore, I argue that the Fed departed from this rule in the summer of 2008 by failing to lower the funds rate in response to sustained weakness in economic activity.

An essential quantity-theory assumption is that central banks are special because of their monopoly over creation of the monetary base--the money used to effect finality fi·nal·i·ty  
n. pl. fi·nal·i·ties
1. The condition or fact of being final.

2. A final, conclusive, or decisive act or utterance.

Noun 1.
 of payment among banks (deposits with the Fed) or among individuals (currency). A central bank is not simply a large commercial bank engaged in intermediating funds between savers and investors. It follows that the central bank controls the behavior of prices through procedures that provide for monetary control. For a central bank using the short-term interest rate (the funds rate) as its policy variable, monetary control imposes a discipline that derives from the role played by the real interest rate in the price system. This discipline takes the form of procedures that must respect Friedman's natural-rate hypothesis, that is, the assumption that the central bank cannot systematically control real variables, like the real interest rate. The implication is that monetary policy procedures must stabilize expected inflation so that changes in the central bank's nominal funds rate target correspond to predictable changes in the real funds rate. These procedures must then cause the real funds rate to track the "natural" interest rate. The natural interest rate is the real interest rate consistent with an amount of aggregate demand that provides for market clearing at full employment. The real interest rate provides the incentive for individuals to change their contemporaneous demand for resources (consumption and investment) relative to that demand in the future in a way that smooths changes in output around trend.

Price theory yields useful intuition for the natural interest rate. Imagine supply and demand schedules for the wheat market. There exists a well-defined dollar price for wheat that clears the market. Similarly, there exists such a dollar price for barley. The ratio of these dollar prices yields a relative (real) price (the barley price of wheat) that clears the market for wheat. If the government uses a commodity-price stabilization program to fix the price of wheat, it will either need to accumulate wheat or to supply it depending upon whether it fixes a price above or below the market-clearing price.

For a central bank with an interest rate instrument, the relevant price is the real rate of interest--the price of resources today measured in terms of resources promised or foregone tomorrow. Note that this price is an intertemporal price whose determination requires analysis in a multiperiod model. Furthermore, the central bank does not create wealth but creates the monetary base, which derives value from its role as a temporary abode One's home; habitation; place of dwelling; or residence. Ordinarily means "domicile." Living place impermanent in character. The place where a person dwells. Residence of a legal voter. Fixed place of residence for the time being.  of purchasing power Purchasing Power

1. The value of a currency expressed in terms of the amount of goods or services that one unit of money can buy. Purchasing power is important because, all else being equal, inflation decreases the amount of goods or services you'd be able to purchase.

2.
. Although money facilitates exchange, it possesses no intrinsic value Intrinsic Value

1. The value of a company or an asset based on an underlying perception of the value.

2. For call options, this is the difference between the underlying stock's price and the strike price.
. Individuals accept money today in return for goods, which satisfy real wants, only because they believe that others will accept goods for money tomorrow. Stability of prices requires the expectation of future stability. Just as with the real interest rate, this intertemporal dimension to the price of money (or the money price of goods--the price level) will also require a multiperiod model. It follows that the public's expectations about the future are essential and that a characterization of central bank policy must elucidate the systematic behavior that shapes these expectations.

Analogously with the market in wheat, if the central bank sets an interest rate that is too low, it will have to create money. Conversely, an interest rate set too high will require destruction of money. An implication of the quantity theory is that such money creation and destruction will require changes in the price level to maintain the real purchasing power of money desired by the public to effect transactions. The quantity theory receives content through the natural-rate assumption that there is a unique market-clearing real interest rate that lies beyond the systematic control of the central bank. As a condition for controlling prices, the central bank must possess systematic procedures for tracking this natural interest rate. (2)

These procedures require consistency (a rule-like character) because of the central role of expectations. What is relevant for macroeconomic mac·ro·ec·o·nom·ics  
n. (used with a sing. verb)
The study of the overall aspects and workings of a national economy, such as income, output, and the interrelationship among diverse economic sectors.
 equilibrium is not only the real funds rate but also the entire term structure of real interest rates. The central bank requires a procedure for changing the funds rate so that, in response to real shocks, financial markets will forecast a behavior of current and future funds rates consistent with a term structure of real interest rates that will moderate fluctuations of real output around trend. Moreover, these procedures must be credible in that financial markets must believe that, in response to shocks, funds rate changes will cumulate to whatever extent necessary to leave trend inflation unchanged (Hetzel 2006 and 2008b).

Credibility for these procedures allows the central bank to influence the way that firms set dollar prices. Specifically, firms will set their dollar prices based on a common assumption about trend inflation (equal to the central bank's inflation target). Moreover, they do not alter that assumption in response to real or inflation shocks. The combination of assumptions that the price level is a monetary phenomenon (the central bank determines trend inflation) and that expectations are rational (consistent with the predictable part of central bank behavior) implies that the central bank can control the expectational environment in which price setters operate. Given stability in this nominal expectational environment, that is, given credibility, the central bank can then set the real funds rate in a way that tracks the natural interest rate and, as a result, allows the private sector to determine real variables such as unemployment.

From the perspective of the quantity theory, the credit-cycle view of the business cycle leads to the mistaken belief that alternating waves of optimism and pessimism overwhelm the stabilizing role of the real interest rate and, by extension, monetary policy. The reason is because of the association of low interest rates (cheap money) with recession and high interest rates (dear money) with booms. For example, the Board of Governors (1943a, 10) stated:
  In the past quarter century it has been demonstrated that policies
  regulating the ... cost of money cannot by themselves produce
  economic stability or even exert a powerful influence in that
  direction. The country has gone through boom conditions
  when ... interest rates were extremely high, and it has continued in
  depression at times when ... money was ... cheap.


The mistake lies in thinking of monetary policy as stimulative when the funds rate is low or as restrictive when it is high. Instead, the focus should be on whether the central bank possesses consistent procedures (a rule) that cause the real funds rate to track the natural rate. A low real interest can still exceed the natural rate if the public is pessimistic enough about the future.

3. LAW WITH CREDIBILITY, MONETARY CONTROL, AND MONETARY DISTURBANCES

An implication of the above formulation of the quantity theory is that there exists a policy procedure (a central bank reaction function) that, when adhered to, yields price and macroeconomic stability but that, when departed from, creates instability. That is, a consistent procedure exists that allows the FOMC to move the funds rate in a way that causes the real funds rate to track the natural interest rate and that provides a nominal anchor. The historical overview in Hetzel (2008a), summarized below, argues for such a baseline policy, labeled "lean-against-the-wind with credibility" and developed by William McChesney Martin (FOMC chairman from the time of the March 1951 Treasury-Fed Accord through January 1970). As encapsulated in Martin's characterization of policy as "lean against the wind" (LAW), the Fed lowers the funds rate in a measured, persistent way in response to sustained decreases in resource utilization rates (increases in unemployment) and conversely in response to sustained increases in resource utilization rates (decreases in unemployment). The Martin FOMC (prior to populist pressures from the Lyndon B. Johnson administration There have been two Presidents of the United States with the surname "Johnson":
  • Andrew Johnson Administration, 17th President of the United States, 1865–1869.
and
  • Lyndon B. Johnson Administration, 36th President of the United States, 1963–1969.
) imposed discipline on the resulting funds rate changes through the requirement that they be consistent with maintaining the expectation of price stability read from the behavior of bond rates (LAW with credibility).

Departures from LAW with credibility correlate with periods of economic instability. After the establishment of the Fed in 1913 and before the 1951 Treasury-Fed Accord, within the Fed, real-bills views predominated. The focus of monetary policy was on limiting the development of asset-price bubbles. The focus on asset prices instead of sustained changes in rates of resource utilization was accompanied by a high degree of economic instability (see Appendix). With LAW, Martin changed the focus of monetary policy from speculation in asset markets to the cyclical behavior of the economy. Also, by looking to bond markets for evidence of "speculative activity" rather than real estate and equity markets, he changed the focus to inflationary expectations and, as a result, credibility for price stability.

Fluctuations in economic activity diminished significantly in the post-Accord period. However, on occasion, the Martin FOMC departed from the nascent LAW-with-credibility procedures. In the period before the August 1957 cyclical peak, the FOMC, concerned about inflation, kept short-term interest rates unchanged despite deterioration in economic activity. Prior to the April 1960 cyclical peak, the FOMC, concerned about balance of payments outflows, kept short-term interest rates unchanged despite deterioration in the economy. In each case, recession followed.

The period known as stop-go began in 1965 when the political system, despite strong economic growth, pressured the Fed not to raise interest rates and thwart its desire to stimulate the economy through the 1964 tax cuts. FOMC chairmen Arthur Burns (February 1970-March 1978) and G. William Miller William Miller or Bill Miller may refer to (items are alphabetized according to the word in boldface): Australia
  • William Miller (Australian athlete) (1847-1939)
  • Bill Miller (film producer)
  • William Miller (minister) (1815-1874)
 (April 1978-July 1979) retained LAW. but imparted cyclical inertia to funds rate changes. After cyclical peaks, the funds rate remained elevated while gross domestic product (GDP GDP (guanosine diphosphate): see guanine. ) growth declined and money growth fell. After cyclical troughs, the funds rate remained low while GDP growth rose and money growth increased (see Hetzel 2008a, Chs. 23-24). The result was procyclical money growth. The view that powerful cost-push factors drove inflation caused Burns and Miller to allow inflation to drift upward across the business cycle (Hetzel 2008a, Chs. 1, 8, 1 1). As a consequence, they destroyed the nominal anchor they had inherited in the form of the expectation that inflation would fluctuate around alow level with periods of relatively high rates followed by periods of relatively low rates. Instead, the expectation of trend inflation drifted with real and inflation shocks.

After stop-go monetary policy, FOMC chairman Paul Volcker (August 1979--July 1987) re-created the Martin LAW-with-credibility procedures, albeit with a nominal anchor in the form of the expectation of low, steady inflation rather than price stability. In doing so, he removed the procyclical bias of money growth characterized as "stop-go." FOMC chairman Alan Greenspan Alan Greenspan

Dr. Greenspan is Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Dr. Greenspan also serves as Chairman of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), the Fed's principal monetary policymaking body.
 (August 1987-January 2006) continued the Volcker version of LAW with credibility. Both Volcker and Greenspan accepted responsibility for the behavior of inflationary expectations as a prerequisite for controlling inflation. After 1979. given the sensitivity of financial markets to inflation, symbolized by the "bond market vigilantes," the result was largely to remove the cyclical inertia in funds rate movements that had characterized the earlier stop-go period. The significant degree of economic stability that characterized the Volcker-Greenspan era earned the appellation ap·pel·la·tion  
n.
1. A name, title, or designation.

2. A protected name under which a wine may be sold, indicating that the grapes used are of a specific kind from a specific district.

3. The act of naming.
 of The Great Moderation.

However, in the Volcker-Greenspan era. the FOMC departed from the baseline LAW-with-credibility procedures twice. In each instance, mini go-stop cycles ensued. The go phases began with a reluctance to raise the funds rate in response to strong real growth because of a concern that the foreign exchange value of the dollar would rise. The first episode occurred with the Louvre Accord Louvre Accord

1987 agreement between countries to attempt to stabilize the value of the US dollar.
 in early 1987 and the second occurred with the Asia crisis, which began in earnest in the fall of 1997 (Hetzel 2008a, Chs. 14, 17-19). Each time, with a lag, inflation began to rise and with the rise in inflation the FOMC responded with significant funds rate increases. (3)

LAW with credibility treats the interest rate as part of the price system and creates a nominal anchor by stabilizing the public's expectation of inflation. The LAW characteristic of moving the funds rate in response to sustained changes in rates of resource utilization embodies a search procedure for discovering the natural interest rate. The constraint that financial markets anticipate that, in response to macroeconomic shocks, the Fed's rule will cause funds rate changes to cumulate to whatever extent necessary to prevent a change in the trend inflation rate set by the central bank's (implicit) inflation target creates a nominal anchor in the form of the expectation of low, stable inflation. By maintaining expected inflation equal to its steady (albeit implicit) target for inflation, the Fed controls the nominal expectational environment that shapes the price-setting behavior of forward-looking firms setting prices over multiple periods. Credibility thus allows the Fed to control trend inflation while allowing inflation shocks (relative price changes that pass through to the price level) to cause headline (total or noncore) inflation to fluctuate around trend inflation. (4)

Friedman (1960, 87) proposed a rule for steady money growth because of the assumption that responding directly to inflation creates monetary shocks to the real economy. The LAW-with-credibility rule is in that spirit in that it maintains steady expected trend inflation while allowing the price level to vary because of transitory real and inflation shocks. With the energy price shock that began in the summer of 2004, central banks initially allowed headline inflation Headline inflation is a measure of the total inflation within an economy and is affected by areas of the market which may experience sudden inflationary spikes such as food or energy.  to rise. I argue in the next section that the world's major central banks, in the summer of 2008, despite deteriorating economic activity, became unwilling to lower their policy rates because of fear that headline inflation in excess of core inflation would raise inflationary expectations. The resulting monetary stringency turned a moderate recession into a major recession.

The FOMC's LAW-with-credibility procedures possess a straightforward interpretation in terms of monetary control. Through a rule that makes the real funds rate track the natural rate as a consequence of its interest rate target, the Fed accommodates the demand for money associated with trend growth in the real economy. Money growth then equals the following components: (1) an amount consistent with trend real growth; (2) expected trend inflation (the FOMC's implicit inflation target); (3) changes in the demand for money because of changes in market interest rates relative to the own rate on money; (4) random changes in the demand for money; and (5) transitory deviations of headline inflation from trend inflation because of inflation shocks (Hetzel 2005, 2006, and 2008b). If the FOMC departs from such a rule so that the real funds rate does a poor job of tracking the natural rate, as explained by Wicksell ([1898] 1962), the resulting money creation (for a real interest rate below the natural rate) or money destruction (for a real interest rate above the natural rate) will engender instability in the price level.

However, given both instability in money demand and heightened interest sensitivity of money demand since 1981 and, recently, given inflation shocks, money growth has become uninformative un·in·for·ma·tive  
adj.
Providing little or no information; not informative.



unin·for
 about whether monetary policy is expansionary ex·pan·sion·ar·y  
adj.
Tending toward or causing expansion: the empire's expansionary policies in Asia. 
 or contractionary measured according to the Wicksellian criterion of central bank success in tracking the real interest rate. As a result, the Friedman (1960) rule for steady money growth is not feasible. The FOMC's pragmatically derived LAW-with-credibility procedures are a better alternative. Even with stability of money demand, as long as the FOMC follows procedures such that the real funds rate tracks the natural rate, money possesses no predictive power The predictive power of a scientific theory refers to its ability to generate testable predictions. Theories with strong predictive power are highly valued, because the predictions can often encourage the falsification of the theory.  for inflation.

4. MONETARY POLICY IN 2008

What caused the appearance of a deep recession after almost three decades of relatively mild economic fluctuations? The explanation here highlights a monetary policy shock in the form of a failure by the Fed to follow a decline in the natural interest rate with reductions in the funds rate. (5) Specifically, the absence of a funds rate reduction between April 30, 2008, and October 8, 2008 (or only a quarter-percentage-point reduction between March 18, 2008, and October 8, 2008), despite deterioration in economic activity, represented a contractionary departure from the policy of LAW with credibility. (6) From mid-March 2008 through mid-September 2008, M2 barely rose while bank credit fell somewhat (Board of Governors 2009a). Moreover, the FOMC effectively tightened monetary policy in June by pushing up the expected path of the federal funds rate Federal Funds Rate

The interest rate at which a depository institution lends immediately available funds (balances at the Federal Reserve) to another depository institution overnight.
 through the hawkish statements of its members. In May 2008, federal funds Federal Funds

Funds deposited to regional Federal Reserve Banks by commercial banks, including funds in excess of reserve requirements.

Notes:
These non-interest bearing deposits are lent out at the Fed funds rate to other banks unable to meet overnight reserve
 futures had been predicting a basically unchanged funds rate at 2 percent for the remainder of 2008. However, by June 18, futures markets predicted a funds rate of 2.5 percent for November 2008. (7)

The U.S. economy weakened steadily throughout 2008. Positive real GDP growth in 2008: Q2 initially appeared reassuring, but the 2.8 percent annualized annualized

Of or relating to a variable that has been mathematically converted to a yearly rate. Inflation and interest rates are generally annualized since it is on this basis that these two variables are ordinarily stated and compared.
 real growth that quarter was more than accounted for by an unsustainable increase in net exports, which added 2.9 percentage points to GDP growth ("final" figures available at the end of September 2008). By mid-July, it had become apparent that the temporary fillip to consumer expenditure offered by the tax rebate had run its course. (8) Retail sales for June, with numbers available July 15, increased only .1 percent. In mid-July, USA Today (2008) ran a front-page headline, "Signs of a growing crisis: 'Relentless flow' of bad economic news suggests there's no easy way out." From June 2008 through September 2008, industrial production fell 5.4 percent (not at an annualized rate).

The steady weakening in economic activity appeared in payroll employment, which slopped growing in December 2007 and then turned consistently negative. The unemployment rate rose steadily from 4.7 percent in November 2007 to 6.1 percent in September 2008. Macroeconomic Advisers (2008c, 1) forecast below-trend growth for 2008:Q3 from May onward (consistently below 2 percent and near zero starting in October). It forecast less than 1 percent growth for 2008:Q4 starting in August and - 1 percent starting in October. (9) Macroeconomic Advisers was among the most optimistic of forecasters. The consensus forecasts reported in Blue Chip Financial Forecasts (2008) on July 1, 2008. for 2008:Q3 and 2008:Q4, respectively, were 1.2 percent and .9 percent. On August 1, they were 1 percent and .3 percent.

The recession intensified in 2008:Q3 (annualized real GDP growth of -.5 percent). That fact suggests that, prior to the significant wealth destruction from the sharp fall in equity markets after mid-September 2008, the real funds rate already exceeded the natural rate. The huge wealth destruction after that date must have further depressed the natural interest rate and made monetary policy even more restrictive. It follows that the fundamental reason for the heightened decline in economic activity in 2008:Q4 and 2009:Q1 was inertia in the decline in the funds rate relative to a decline in the natural rate produced by the continued fall in real income from the housing price and inflation shock reinforced by a dramatic quickening in the fall in equity wealth.

In 2008, all the world's major central banks introduced inertia in their interest rate targets relative to the cyclical decline in output. The European Central Bank (ECB See electronic code book. ) focused on higher wage settlements in Germany, Italy, and the Netherlands (Financial Times 2008) and in July 2008 raised the interbank rate to 4.25 percent. Although annualized real GDP growth in the Euro area declined in 2008:Q1, 2008:Q2, and 2008:Q3, respectively, from 2.8 percent, to -1 percent, to -1 percent, the ECB began lowering its bank rate only on October 8, 2008. In Great Britain Great Britain, officially United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland, constitutional monarchy (2005 est. pop. 60,441,000), 94,226 sq mi (244,044 sq km), on the British Isles, off W Europe. The country is often referred to simply as Britain. , the Bank of England Bank of England, central bank and note-issuing institution of Great Britain. Popularly known as the Old Lady of Threadneedle Street, its main office stands on the street of that name in London.  kept the bank rate at 5 percent through the summer, unchanged after a quarter-point reduction on April 10, From 2007:Q4 through 2008:Q3, annualized real GDP growth rates Growth Rates

The compounded annualized rate of growth of a company's revenues, earnings, dividends, or other figures.

Notes:
Remember, historically high growth rates don't always mean a high rate of growth looking into the future.
 in Great Britain declined, respectively, from 2.2 percent, to 1.6 percent, to -.1 percent, and then to -2.8 percent. (The Bank of England also lowered its bank rate by 50 basis points on October 8, 2008.) In Japan, for the quarters from 2007:Q4-2008:Q3, annualized real GDP growth declined from 4.0 percent, to 1.4 percent, to -4.5 percent, to -1.4 percent. The Bank of Japan kept its interbank rate at .5 percent, unchanged from February 2007, until October 31, 2008, when it lowered the rate to .3 percent. The fact that the severe contraction in output began in all these countries in 2008:Q2 is more readily explained by a common restrictive monetary policy than by contagion Contagion

The likelihood of significant economic changes in one country spreading to other countries. This can refer to either economic booms or economic crises.

Notes:
An infamous example is the "Asian Contagion" that occurred in 1997 and started in Thailand.
 from the then still-mild U.S. recession.

In early fall 2008, the realization emerged that recession would not be confined to the United States but would be worldwide. That realization, as much as the difficulties caused by the Lehman bankruptcy, produced the decrease in equity wealth in the fall of 2008 as evidenced by the fact that broad measures of equity markets fell by the same amount as the value of bank stocks. Between September 19, 2008, and October 27, 2008, the Wilshire 5000 stock index fell 34 percent. Over this period, the KBW KBW Kommunistischer Bund Westdeutschlands (Communist Union of West Germany)
KBW Keefe, Bruyette and Woods, Inc. (investment firm)
KBW Knowledge-Based Warfare
 bank equity index fell 38 percent. (10) Between 2007:Q3 and 2008:Q4, the net worth of households fell 19.9 percent with a fall of 9 percent in 2008:Q4 alone (Board of Governors 2009b). Significant declines in household wealth have occurred at other times, for example, in 1969-1970, 1974-1975. and 2000-2003. However, during those declines in wealth, consumption has always been considerably more stable, at least since 1955 when the wealth series became available. That fact renders especially striking the sharp decline in the growth rate of real personal consumption expenditures from 1.2 percent in 2008:Q2 to -3.8 percent and -4.3 percent in 2008:Q3 and 2008:Q4. This decline in consumption suggests that the public expected the fall in wealth to be permanent. The sharp rise in the unemployment rate from 5.0 percent in April 2008 to 8.1 percent in February 2009 added to individual pessimism and uncertainty about the future. These factors must have produced a decline in the natural rate.

Restrictive monetary policy rather than the deleveraging in financial markets that had begun in August 2007 offers a more direct explanation of the intensification of the recession that began in the summer of 2008. By then, U.S. financial markets were reasonably calm. (11) The intensification of the recession began before the financial turmoil that followed the September 15, 2008, Lehman bankruptcy. (12) Although from mid-2007 through mid-December 2008, financial institutions reported losses of $1 trillion dollars, they also raised $930 billion in capital--$346 billion from governments and $585 billion from the private sector (Institute of International Finance 2008, 2). (13)

In this recession, unlike the other recessions that followed the Depression, commentators have assigned causality causality, in philosophy, the relationship between cause and effect. A distinction is often made between a cause that produces something new (e.g., a moth from a caterpillar) and one that produces a change in an existing substance (e.g.  to dysfunction in credit markets. For example, Financial Times columnist Martin Wolf Martin Wolf is a British journalist. He is associate editor and chief economics commentator at the Financial Times. He was awarded the CBE (Commander of the British Empire) in 2000.  (2008) wrote about "the origins of the crisis in the collapse of an asset price bubble and consequent disintegration of the credit mechanism. ..." This view implies a structural break in the cyclical behavior of bank lending: In the current recession, bank lending should have been a leading indicator Leading Indicator

A measurable economic factor that changes before the economy starts to follow a particular pattern or trend. Leading indicators are used to predict changes in the economy, but are not always accurate.
 and should have declined more significantly than in past recessions. However, Figure 1, which shows the behavior of real (inflation-adjusted) bank loans in recessions, reveals that bank lending behaved similarly in this recession to other post-war recessions. Moreover, the fact that bank lending rose in the severe 1981-1982 recession and often recovered only after cyclical troughs suggests that bank lending is not a reliable tool for the management of aggregate demand.

Based on the judgment that dysfunction in credit markets was the cause of the intensification of the recession, governments and central banks intervened massively in financial markets. Starting with the term auction facility (TAF TAF
abbr.
tumor angiogenic factor
) in December 2007, the Fed initiated programs to lower risk premia in particular markets through its assumption of private credit risk. Since September 15, 2008, the Fed has taken an unprecedented amount of private debt onto its balance sheet in an attempt to influence the flow of credit in particular markets. The size of its balance sheet went from about $800 billion before September 15, 2008, to more than $2,000 trillion at year-end 2008. It has lent to financial institutions through the discount window (with the primary credit facility to banks, as well as the primary dealer credit facility and TAF) and to foreign central banks through currency swaps. It has purchased significant amounts of commercial paper through the commercial paper funding facility in an attempt to revive that market.

Government has taken over significant amounts of portfolio risk in large financial institutions, in particular, AIG AIG addressee indicator group (US DoD)
AIG American International Group, Inc
AiG Answers in Genesis (religious group in defense of Scripture)
AIG Artificial Intelligence Group
AIG Australian Industry Group
, Citigroup, and Bank of America
See also:  and


Bank of America (NYSE: BAC TYO: 8648 ) is the largest commercial bank in the United States in terms of deposits, and the largest company of its kind in the world.
. The Treasury has supported the government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs) and the deposits of money market mutual funds. The Federal Deposit Insurance Coporation has guaranteed the debt of large commercial banks and small industrial banks and has extended the coverage of insured deposits. Troubled Asset Relief Program money has added capital to the banking system. Foreign governments have implemented similar programs.

Perhaps the scale of this intervention in credit markets has simply been insufficient to overcome financial market malfunction. Still, the scale of the intervention has been vast. If the problem has not been financial market dysfunction but rather has been misalignment mis·a·ligned  
adj.
Incorrectly aligned.



misa·lignment n.
 between the real funds rate and the natural rate, then intervention in credit markets will only increase intermediation in the subsidized markets. Those subsidies will not reduce aggregate risk to the point that the overall cost of funds Cost of Funds

The interest rate paid on an outstanding loan.

Notes:
Money isn't free! Cost of funds is the cost of borrowing money.
See also: Interest Rate



Cost of funds

Interest rate associated with borrowing money.
 falls enough to stimulate investment by businesses and consumers. Government intervention in credit markets is, then, not a reliable tool for the management of aggregate demand because such interventions do little to reduce the public's uncertainty and pessimism about the future that have depressed the natural rate.

To understand why policymakers are now at a crossroads about how to think about monetary policy, consider the reasons for the widespread unwillingness to lower the funds rate in the summer of 2008. There was a consensus that monetary policy was "accommodative" as evidenced by the low level of the nominal funds rate and realized real funds rate (the nominal rate minus realized inflation). The debate revolved around whether the "low" level of the funds rate was appropriate given slow growth in the economy or whether it would lead to a rise in inflation. There was a shared concern that headline inflation persistently in excess of participants' implicit inflation objectives would raise the public's expectation of inflation above the lower, basically satisfactory, core inflation rate and thereby propagate the higher headline inflation rate into the future.

As evidenced by a Wall Street Journal (Evans 2008) headline on the day of the August FOMC meeting ("Price Increases Ramp Up Ramp Up

To increase a company's operations in anticipation of increased demand.

Notes:
A company might 'ramp up' operations if they just signed a contract creating substantially more demand for their product.
See also: Demand, Economies of Scale
, Sounding Inflation Alarm"), the increase in energy and food prices had significantly increased headline inflation. The numbers available at the meeting showed three-month headline consumer price index (CPI (1) (Characters Per Inch) The measurement of the density of characters per inch on tape or paper. A printer's CPI button switches character pitch.

(2) (Counts Per I
) inflation ending in June 2008 at 7.9 percent with 12-month inflation at 5.0 percent. The corresponding core (ex food and energy) CPI figures were, respectively, 2.5 percent and 2.4 percent. For the PCE PCE pseudocholinesterase; see cholinesterase.
erythromycin

Apo-Erythro (CA), Apo-Erythro-EC, Diomycin (CA), E-Base, E-Mycin, Erybid (CA), Erymax (UK), Ery-Tab, Erythromid (CA), PCE (CA), Rommix (UK), Tiloryth (UK)

 (personal consumption expenditures deflator Deflator

A statistical factor used to convert current dollar purchasing power into inflation-adjusted purchasing power. Enables the comparison of prices while accounting for inflation in two different time periods.
), the three-month number was 5.7 percent with the 12-month number at 3.8 percent. The corresponding core PCE figures were, respectively, 2.1 percent and 2.3 percent. Earlier, Chairman Bernanke (2008) had signaled concern that inflationary expectations could increase, as well as a concern that the dollar would depreciate depreciate v. in accounting, to reduce the value of an asset each year theoretically on the basis that the assets (such as equipment, vehicles or structures) will eventually become obsolete, worn out and of little value. (See: depreciation) :
  Another significant upside risk to inflation is that high headline
  inflation, if sustained, might lead the public to expect higher
  long-term inflation rates, an expectation that could ultimately
  become self-confirming. ... We are attentive to the implications of
  changes in the value of the dollar for inflation and inflation
  expectations and will continue to formulate policy to guard against
  risks to both parts of our dual mandate, including the risk of an
  erosion in longer-term inflation expectations.


In its regular publication "FOMC Chatter," Macroeconomic Advisers (2008a, 1) reviewed the public statements of FOMC participants made before the June 2008 FOMC meeting:
  FOMC members left little doubt about their concerns regarding longer
  term inflation expectations. Chairman Bernanke (6/9/08) said that the
  FOMC "will strongly resist" any increase in expectations. Vice
  Chairman Kohn (6/11/08) said that keeping expectations anchored is
  "critical," and Governor Mishkin (6/10/08) said that it is
  "absolutely critical." ... President Fisher (6/10/08) said that an
  increase in expectations is "the worst conceivable thing that can
  happen." Presidents Plosser (6/12/08), Bullard (6/11/08), and Lacker
  each emphasized the need to tighten promptly enough to prevent any
  increase in inflation expectations. (14)


What is the crossroads that policymakers face? The view that in the summer of 2008 monetary policy was accommodative combined with the association of financial market disruption Market Disruption

A situation where markets cease to function in a regular manner, typically characterized by rapid and large market declines. Market disruptions can result from both physical threats to the stock exchange or a unusual trading (as in a crash).
 with intensification of the recession has led to a revival of the credit-cycle view of cyclical instability. Current debate has recreated much of the sentiment expressed by the Board of Governors in the 1920s that regulatory constraints on credit extension should complement the funds rate as a mechanism for controlling excessive risk-taking by banks. Friedman and Schwartz (1963a, 254) wrote, "[T]he view attributed to the Board [in the 1920s] was that direct pressure was a feasible means of restricting the availability of credit for speculative purposes without unduly restricting its availability for productive purposes, whereas rises in discount rates or open market sales sufficiently severe to curb speculation would be too severe for business in general." Just as in the Depression with the use of the Reconstruction Finance Corporation Reconstruction Finance Corporation (RFC), former U.S. government agency, created in 1932 by the administration of Herbert Hoover. Its purpose was to facilitate economic activity by lending money in the depression.  to recapitalize banks, the focus of current monetary policy is on encouraging financial intermediation (see Appendix).

The alternative road lies with the extension of the policy changes taken in the Volcker-Greenspan era. In this spirit, the FOMC should be willing to move the funds rate up and down to whatever extent necessary to respond to changes in rates of resource utilization. The issue then is credibility. With credibility, in the event of an inflation shock, the FOMC can still move the funds rate down to zero without an increase in inflationary expectations. The absence of an explicit inflation target voted on by the entire FOMC would appear as a weakness in current procedures. An explicit inflation target then raises the issue of how to interpret the Fed mandate for "stable prices" and whether that part of the mandate conflicts with "maximum employment." (15) Also, as discussed in the next section, the absence of an explicit strategy for dealing with the ZLB problem is a deficiency.

5. MONETARY POLICY AND THE ZERO-LOWER-BOUND PROBLEM

The hypothesis advanced here is that the accelerated loss of wealth in the fall of 2008 pushed the natural interest rate further below the real interest rate. The Fed began again to lower the funds rate on October 10, 2008 (from 2 percent to 1.5 percent), and on October 29 to 1 percent and on December 16, 2008, to a range from 0 percent to .25 percent. At the time of this writing (May 2009), tentative indications of a cyclical trough in 2009:Q2 indicate that these funds rate reductions may have restored monetary neutrality by pushing the real rate in line with the natural interest rate or may have provided monetary stimulus by pushing the real rate below the natural rate. In any event, it is desirable for the FOMC to possess a strategy for providing monetary stimulus with a zero-funds rate that coexists with a real funds rate in excess of the natural interest rate. (16)

How should central banks deal with the ZLB problem? To begin, note that a discrete increase in the degree of monetary instability (measured by an increase in the unpredictability of the evolution of the price level precipitated by a departure of the central bank from a stabilizing rule) depresses the natural rate of interest, albeit in a way that does not allow for its systematic manipulation. The reason is that unanticipated monetary restriction causes the price system to convey information about the relative scarcity of resources less efficiently. Because of the unanticipated nature of the monetary shock, there is no way for firms to lower the dollar prices of their products in a coordinated way that preserves relative prices. Because individuals become more pessimistic about the future (expected consumption falls relative to current consumption), the natural rate falls.

With a zero-funds rate, monetary policy is contractionary if the natural rate (NR) lies below the negative value of expected inflation (-[[pi].sup.e]); that is, the real rate (rr) exceeds the natural rate: rr = (0 - [[pi].sup.e]) > NR, Assuming that the central bank cannot manipulate short-term expected inflation, it must resort to money creation to raise the natural rate. Sustained money creation will revive the spending of the public through a portfolio rebalancing effect. The natural rate rises with no increase in expected inflation as the increase in spending restores confidence in the economy.

The proposal here for providing monetary stimulus at the ZLB in recession is for the Fed to engage in significant open market purchases of long-term government securities to boost the monetary aggregate M2 to a level that constitutes a significant fraction of GDP and then to maintain significant growth of M2 until recovery begins. (The ratio of M2 to GDP, the inverse of velocity, has been somewhat in excess of 50 percent in recent years.) The Treasury could issue these securities directly to the Fed and use the proceeds to fund expenditure rather than reduce its debt. With the emergence of a nascent recovery, the Fed would again make the funds rate positive. A positive funds rate would absorb the monetary overhang Monetary overhang is a phenomenon where people have money holdings due to the lack of ability to spend them. This is a phenomenon often present with repressed inflation and was a common occurrence in the Soviet Union. The solution to this is usually a swift burst of inflation.  that will emerge with economic recovery and positive interest rates. (17)

The reason for an initial large increase in money is uncertainty over the lag between monetary acceleration and economic recovery. Friedman and Schwartz (1963b) documented a two-to-three-quarter lag between changes in money growth and changes in growth of nominal expenditure. Friedman used this estimate to forecast successfully the behavior of the business cycle in the stop-go period of monetary policy. However, in recessions in the stop-go period, because of the high level of interest rates, the Fed could push the nominal funds rate down until the real funds rate fell below the natural rate. The cyclical trough in GDP during that period occurred after monetary policy became expansionary by this Wicksellian measure. If indeed the real rate exceeds the natural rate at the ZLB, to reach this position, money must first expand by enough to stimulate expenditure sufficiently to raise the natural rate up to and then above the real funds rate.

6. CONCLUDING COMMENT

The companion piece to this paper (Hetzel 2009a) begins with a graph of output per capita [Latin, By the heads or polls.] A term used in the Descent and Distribution of the estate of one who dies without a will. It means to share and share alike according to the number of individuals.  from 1970 to the present. The graph displays a dramatic rising trend but also significant departures below trend. The rising trend highlights how free markets create wealth. The departures below trend point to times of widespread misery during recession. Given the insatiability of human wants, macroeconomics must explain why, at times, individuals demand less output than is consistent with full utilization of productive resources. What prevents the price system from adjusting to prevent periodic underutilization of resources?

Hetzel (2008a) answers that central banks have exacerbated cyclical fluctuations through introducing inertia at cyclical peaks into declines in the real interest rate with money destruction (deceleration deceleration /de·cel·er·a·tion/ (de-sel?er-a´shun) decrease in rate or speed.

early deceleration
) and through introducing inertia at cyclical troughs into increases in the real interest rate with money creation (acceleration). Hetzel (2008a) also argues for explicit recognition of LAW with credibility as a rule. In the Volcker-Greenspan era, these procedures allowed market forces to determine the real interest rate while providing a nominal anchor in the form of stable, low expected inflation. At present, there is no consensus about either the desirability of a monetary rule in general or about the particular form of a rule. The Fed should take responsibility for achievement of such a consensus by explaining its behavior in terms of what is consistent over time in its behavior and by highlighting in its Minutes reasons for departures. Such communication would allow an ongoing debate with the academic community about policy. (18)

Knut Wicksell Johan Gustaf Knut Wicksell (December 20, 1851 in Stockholm – May 3, 1926 in Stocksund) was a Swedish economist. Biography
Wicksell was born in Stockholm, Sweden on December 20, 1851. His father was a relatively successful businessman and real estate broker.
 ([1935] 1978, 3) wrote in his Lectures on Political Economy:
  [W]ith regard to money, everything is determined by human beings
  themselves, i.e. the statesmen, and (so far as they are consulted)
  the economists; the choice of a measure of value, of a monetary
  system, of currency and credit legislation--all are in the hands of
  society. ...


Wicksell followed up by noting:
  The establishment of a greater, and if possible absolute, stability
  in the value of money has thus become one of the most important
  practical objectives of political economy. But, unfortunately, little
  progress towards the solution of this problem has. so far, been made.


As Wicksell noted, the monetary arrangements of a country are subject to rational design. However, since the founding of the Republic, a weakness in American institutions has been the inability to bring monetary institutions into the general constitutional framework. If the United States is to preserve the ability of free markets to create wealth, economists and policymakers, along with the general public, will have to use the current situation to design monetary arrangements capable of assuring economic stability.

Dialogue between monetary policymakers and the academic community is one of the important means through which such a constructive response can emerge. Central banks have done little in the past to prepare for such a dialogue. William McChesney Martin. FOMC chairman from March 1951 until January 1970, established the practice of moving short-term money market rates of interest (later the funds rate) in response to the behavior of economic-activity. Policymakers then talked about monetary policy using the descriptive language of the business economist, that is, in terms of near-term forecasts of the economy. They characterized funds rate changes as chosen optimally period-by-period in the context of the contemporaneous behavior of the economy. This language of discretion implicitly rejects the Lucas ([1976] 1981) critique, which argues for thinking of policy as a consistent strategy or rule. (19) Without the language of economics, which places policy within the framework of the price system and explicit frictions, and without the language of rules, policymakers cannot debate academics over contrasting frameworks for thinking about monetary policy and the consequences of alternative policies (Koopmans 1947).

The credit intermediation of commercial banks and the money creation of central banks have proven difficult to place within institutional frameworks that protect property rights (Hetzel 1997). Debt guarantees, the GSEs, and the financial safety net allow the political system to allocate credit to politically influential constituencies in ways that do not appear on budget. Monetary base creation provides tax revenue in the form of seigniorage seigniorage

Charge over and above the expenses of coinage that is deducted from the bullion brought to a mint to be coined. From early times, coinage was the prerogative of kings, who prescribed the amount they were to receive as seigniorage.
 that does not require explicit legislation. Central bank independence is a safeguard against the abuse of seigniorage, but that independence still allows for significant competition for control over the objectives of the central bank (Hetzel 1990). In this adversarial environment, central banks do not systematically review their history to evaluate what they did right and especially what they did wrong. Without the learning provided by such review, they cannot contribute to a debate on the optimal design of monetary policy.

The spirit of the critique offered here is that the Federal Reserve needs a new dual mandate A dual mandate is a term used for a person who has been elected to two different bodies with different competencies, for example being a member of both a national legislature, and of a local authority. . It would charge the Fed with providing for price stability and with allowing the price system to determine unemployment, along with other real variables. Everything about monetary policy is controversial. However, open debate is critical. Monetary arrangements that provide for monetary stability are a prerequisite for the long-term survival of a free market economy.

APPENDIX: LESSONS FROM THE DEPRESSION

This Appendix summarizes Hetzel (2008a, Ch. 3), Until recently, the absence of credit allocation has defined modern central banking. Because of the lack of instances in which central banks used the composition of their balance sheet to affect the aggregate expenditure of the public by influencing credit flows, there is little historical basis for evaluating the efficacy of credit policy. However, experience in the Depression allows one to evaluate both credit-channel and money-creation policies. Because the government implemented credit policy in the Depression, these two policies followed different paths. (If the Fed had expanded the asset side of its balance sheet to purchase debt in markets it deemed dysfunctional, then, left unsterilized, the associated increase in the monetary base would have confounded the credit and money creation effects.) In the Depression, the government ran policies for intervening in credit markets, for example, by using the Reconstruction Finance Corporation (RFC (Request For Comments) A document that describes the specifications for a recommended technology. Although the word "request" is in the title, if the specification is ratified, it becomes a standards document. ) to recapitalize banks. The resulting independence of money-creation and credit-channel policies makes the Depression a laboratory for evaluating the usefulness of these different policies for macroeconomic stabilization.

The founders of the Federal Reserve attributed financial panics and recession to the inevitable collapse of asset speculation. As a result, they designed the Federal Reserve Act according to the real-bills doctrine, which prescribed limiting credit extension to the amount required to finance real bills (the self-liquidating IOUs used to finance goods in the process of production). Such limitation, it was hoped, would prevent an excess of credit creation that would spill over Verb 1. spill over - overflow with a certain feeling; "The children bubbled over with joy"; "My boss was bubbling over with anger"
bubble over, overflow

seethe, boil - be in an agitated emotional state; "The customer was seething with anger"

2.
 into asset markets for land and stocks and create asset bubbles. In 1928, Fed policymakers believed that the increase in the value of stocks on the New York Stock Exchange New York Stock Exchange (NYSE)

World's largest marketplace for securities. The exchange began as an informal meeting of 24 men in 1792 on what is now Wall Street in New York City.
 represented a speculative bubble that required deflating (Friedman and Schwartz 1963a, 254ff, and Meltzer 2003, 224ff).

In 1928, the Fed started raising interest rates in order to bring down the value of the stock market. Even after recession appeared, the Fed kept market rates at a level high enough to prevent a reemergence of the speculation presumed to have initiated a boom-bust credit cycle. It maintained positive discount window-borrowing, which together with a positive discount rate meant keeping interest rates elevated. The resulting monetary contraction that led to the initial recession turned that recession into a depression as a result of a self-reinforcing cycle of monetary contraction, deflation, expected deflation, the transformation of positive nominal rates into high real rates, and then reinforced monetary contraction and so on. (See Figures 3.1 and 3.4 on inflation and money growth and Table 3.1 on nominal and real interest rates in Hetzel [2008a].) Contractionary monetary policy appeared in the decline of the money stock. From 1930:Q1 to 1933:Q2, Ml fell by 25 percent and M2 fell by 32 percent (money growth figures from Friedman and Schwartz [1970, Table 1]). That decline in turn manifested itself in the failure of smaller banks as depositors withdrew their deposits and redeposited them in larger banks, which they considered safer (Walter 2005).

Two events ended the first of the two back-to-back recessions that defined the Great Depression. First, in response to a series of bank failures finishing in the winter of 1932-1933, banks accumulated large amounts of excess reserves Excess reserves

Amount of reserves held by an institution in excess of its reserve requirement and required clearing balance. Also see reserves.


Excess reserves

Actual reserves that exceed required reserves.
 as a source of funds alternative to borrowing from the discount window. From basically frictional levels in early 1932, member bank excess reserves rose steadily through 1935. Borrowed reserves Borrowed reserves

Funds borrowed from a Federal Reserve Bank by member banks to maintain the required reserve ratios.
 obtained through the Fed's discount window fell steadily after March 1933 until reaching frictional levels in late 1933 or early 1934 (Board of Governors 1943b). When banks had accumulated sufficient excess reserves, they no longer required access to the discount window to meet their marginal reserve needs, and the Fed no longer determined market interest rates. The Fed then withdrew as an active central bank and confined itself to maintaining the size of its government securities holdings at a fixed level. As a result, the Fed gave up control over the monetary base and money creation.

The second event critical to precipitating the initial recovery was Roosevelt's attempt to raise the domestic price level by raising commodity prices through depreciation of the dollar. Gold purchases, along with the prohibition on the export of gold, increased the dollar price of gold and, as a result, the dollar prices of commodities, whose gold prices were determined in international markets. The expectation of inflation that emerged from this policy turned formerly high positive real interest rates into negative rates (see Hetzel [2008a], Table 3.1). Very quickly, economic recovery replaced economic decline. Dollar devaluation devaluation, decreasing the value of one nation's currency relative to gold or the currencies of other nations. It is usually undertaken as a means of correcting a deficit in the balance of payments.  in early 1934 combined with political unrest in Europe to create gold inflows that augmented the monetary base and money. From 1933:Q2 to 1936:Q3, M1 grew at an annualized rate of 14.3 percent and M2 at 11.4 percent. Money creation allowed the economy to grow vigorously until 1937.

In the summer of 1936 and the first half of 1937, the Fed acted on its desire to again control market interest rates. Through a series of increases in required reserves Required reserves

The dollar amounts, based on reserve ratios, that banks are required to keep on deposit at a Federal Reserve Bank.


required reserves 
 (effective August 1936, March 1937. and May 1937), the Fed reduced banks' excess reserves with the intention of forcing banks back into the discount window and thus reviving its control over market rates. At the same time, the Treasury began to sterilize sterilize /ster·i·lize/ (ster´i-liz)
1. to render sterile; to free from microorganisms.

2. to render incapable of reproduction.


ster·il·ize
v.
1.
 gold inflows. The Fed's intent was to resurrect its pre-1933 operating procedures. When the demand for bank credit revived, banks would therefore have to obtain the additional reserves associated with the increase in loans and deposits from the discount window. Market rates would then rise and prevent a revival of the speculation that had supposedly caused an unsustainable bubble in stock prices in the 1920s.

As banks attempted to offset their loss of excess reserves, the money stock stopped growing. Money growth declined after 1936:Q3. Thereafter the level of money fell moderately from 1937:Q1 through 1937:Q4. The level of money remained basically unchanged in the first half of 1938. Money began to rise when banks restored the pre-reserve-requirement level of excess reserves in 1938:Q2. Money then began to rise steadily, basically coincident with the cyclical trough in June 1938 when recession replaced recovery. A chastened chas·ten  
tr.v. chas·tened, chas·ten·ing, chas·tens
1. To correct by punishment or reproof; take to task.

2. To restrain; subdue: chasten a proud spirit.

3.
 Fed retreated from its attempt to again become an active central bank and continued to freeze its holdings of government securities. Monetary base and money growth resumed with gold inflows and the end of Treasury sterilization sterilization

Any surgical procedure intended to end fertility permanently (see contraception). Such operations remove or interrupt the anatomical pathways through which the cells involved in fertilization travel (see reproductive system).
 (Friedman and Schwartz 1963a, Chart 40, and Friedman and Schwartz 1970, Table 1). Because inflation (CPI) turned to deflation in 1937:Q4, the trough in real Ml occurred in 1937:Q4. The return of growth after the business cycle trough in June 1938 is consistent with the increase in real Ml stimulating expenditure through portfolio rebalancing, that is, through a stimulative real-balance effect (Patinkin 1948, 1965).

As summarized in the equation of exchange, nominal money Nominal money, in economics, is the quantity of money measured in a particular currency and is directly proportional to the price level.

This means, among other things, that if the price level rises by 10%, people needs to have 10% more money than before in order to maintain
 (M) times velocity (V), or the rate of turnover of money, equals dollar expenditure. Dollar expenditure equals the price level (P) times real output (y). In algebraic 1. (language) ALGEBRAIC - An early system on MIT's Whirlwind.

[CACM 2(5):16 (May 1959)].
2. (theory) algebraic - In domain theory, a complete partial order is algebraic if every element is the least upper bound of some chain of compact elements.
 terms, M * V = P * y. Without a Fed interest rate peg, short-term interest rates could fall to zero. Furthermore, with money growth powered by gold inflows, a return of expected deflation could not produce a return to the earlier self-reinforcing downward monetary spiral. Because monetary velocity was roughly steady, rapid money growth translated into rapid growth in aggregate dollar spending (P * y). With deflation, this growth in nominal spending appeared as growth in real output (y) after the June 1938 trough in the business cycle.

An important lesson emerges from the comparison of the interest-rate targeting followed by the Fed until March 1933 with the succeeding period of exogenous Exogenous

Describes facts outside the control of the firm. Converse of endogenous.
 monetary base growth. Discussion in the popular press attributes to deflation a depressing effect of economic activity. When the central bank implements policy with an interest rate target, deflation that creates expected deflation is destabilizing. However, if monetary base growth is exogenous, deflation is stimulative because it increases real money and thereby induces portfolio rebalancing and the associated increase in expenditure.

The experience of the Depression casts doubt on the credit-cycle view, which emphasizes the disruption to real economic activity from the loss of banks and the resulting loss of information specific to particular credit markets. Ex-Fed Governor Frederic Mishkin (2008) expressed this idea:
  In late 1930 ... a rolling series of bank panics began. Investments
  made by the banks were going bad. ... Hundreds of banks eventually
  closed. Once a town's bank shut its doors, all the knowledge
  accumulated by the bank officers effectively disappeared. ... Credit
  dried up. ... And that's when the economy collapses.


However, the implications of this view conflict with the commencement of vigorous economic recovery after the business cycle trough on March 1933 and the occurrence of widespread bank failures in the winter of 1933 and the additional permanent closing of banks after the Bank Holiday in March 1933. During the Bank Holiday, which lasted from March 6 through March 13-15, the government closed all commercial banks, including the Federal Reserve Banks. Before the holiday, there were 17,800 commercial banks.Afterward. "... fewer than 12,000 of those were licensed to open and do business" (Friedman and Schwartz 1963a, 425). Friedman and Schwartz (1963a, Table 16, 438) list "Losses to Depositors per $100 of Deposits Adjusted in All Commercial Banks." In 1930, 1931, and 1932, the numbers are, respectively, .6 percent, 1.0 percent, and .6 percent. For 1933, the year in which cyclical recovery began, the number rose to 2.2 percent.

Likewise, the vigorous recovery that began after 1933:Q1 contrasts with the long period of time required by the banking system to work through its bad debts. The following numbers show "net profits as percentage of total capital accounts" for the indicated years: -1.5 (1931), -5.0 (1932), -9.6 (1933), and -5.2 (1934). (20) Despite the protracted pro·tract  
tr.v. pro·tract·ed, pro·tract·ing, pro·tracts
1. To draw out or lengthen in time; prolong: disputants who needlessly protracted the negotiations.

2.
 difficulties in the banking system evidenced by these numbers, real output grew vigorously after the 1933;Q1 cyclical trough. According to Balke and Gordon (1986, Appendix B, Table 2), real GNP GNP

See: Gross National Product
 grew at an annualized rate of 10.7 percent from the 1933:Q1 cyclical trough to the 1937:Q2 cyclical peak. Moreover, the implications of the credit-cycle view conflict with the timing of the 1937:Q2 cyclical peak. In 1935, 1936, and 1937, as evidenced by "net profits as percentage of total capital accounts" of 5.1 percent, 10.0 percent, and 7.1 percent, respectively, banks had returned to good health.

The revival of money growth roughly coincident with the two cyclical troughs of March 1933 (1933:Q1) and June 1938 (1938:Q2) is consistent with the end of a restrictive monetary policy that pushed the real interest rate above the natural interest rate. In each case, there was a "snap back" in output. In the four quarters ending with 1933:Q1, real GNP fell 14.1 percent, and in the four succeeding quarters it rose 13.5 percent. Similarly, in the four quarters ending with 1938:Q2, real GNP fell 10 percent, and in the four succeeding quarters, it rose 7.4 percent. This snap-back in output after each trough supports the hypothesis that, in the absence of monetary restriction, the economy is self-equilibrating in that output returns to trend relatively quickly after shocks.

More generally, Friedman ([1964] 1969, 273) found that the magnitude of an economic contraction An economic contraction is a reduction in goods and services for sale in the market place. Typically it relates to a downturn in production caused by external factors such as weather or a decline in exports, or by such internal factors as taxes, regulatory constraints or other  predicts the magnitude of the subsequent expansion. At the same time, the magnitude of output increases in cyclical expansions fails to forecast the magnitude of subsequent cyclical declines. This latter fact contradicts the implication of credit-cycle explanations of the business cycle that recessions manifest the working out of prior speculative excess. Using data on cyclical expansions and contractions from 1879-1961, Friedman ([1964] 1969, 272) concluded that:
  [T]here appears to be no systematic connection between the size of an
  expansion and of the succeeding contraction. ... This
  phenomenon ... [casts] grave doubts on those theories that see as the
  source of a deep depression the excesses of the prior expansion."


Morley (2009, 3) reconfirmed Friedman's results using quarterly data from 1947:Q2-2008:Q4: "[E]xpansions imply little or no serial correlation for output growth in the immediate future, while recessions imply negative serial correlation in the near term."

Because of the depth of the first cyclical decline and because the second cyclical decline followed fairly closely on the first, the unemployment rate remained high throughout the 1930s. Because of the widespread association of "the Depression" with high unemployment, popular lore holds that only the deficit spending of World War II ended the Depression. In fact, the ending of contractionary monetary policy ended both the cyclical downturns. In the Depression, both the view that monetary policy works through financial intermediation and the existence of low money-market interest rates combined to foster the assumption that monetary policy is impotent in Depression conditions that push the zero nominal short-term interest rate to zero. In reply, Friedman and Schwartz (1963a, 300) wrote, "The contraction [Depression] is in fact a tragic testimonial to the importance of monetary forces."

At the time of the Depression, however, policymakers believed that dysfunction in credit markets propagated an initial shock in the form of a collapse in equity and land prices in 1929. That dysfunction arose from the insolvencies associated with defaults on the excessive issue of debt in the prior speculative boom. As a result, policy focused on the disruption to credit flows rather than the money stock. The Hoover administration created the RFC to recapitalize banks. Bordo (2008, 16) cites Richard Sylla's figure that the RFC's recapitalization Recapitalization

Restructuring a company's debt and equity mixture often with the aim of making a company's capital structure more stable.

Notes:
Companies often want to diversify their debt-to-equity ratio to improve liquidity.
 of 6,000 banks amounted to $200 billion in today's dollars. In 1932, Congress created the Federal Home Loan Bank System Noun 1. Federal Home Loan Bank System - the central credit system for thrift institutions
financial institution, financial organisation, financial organization - an institution (public or private) that collects funds (from the public or other institutions) and
 to encourage housing finance. The Roosevelt administration There have been two Presidents of the United States with the surname "Roosevelt":
  • Theodore Roosevelt Administration, the 26th President of the United States, 1901 - 1909.
and his younger distant cousin
  • Franklin D.
 created numerous additional government entities to revive credit intermediation, for example, Fannie Mae Fannie Mae: see Federal National Mortgage Association. , the Federal Housing Administration Federal Housing Administration (FHA)

Federally sponsored agency chartered in 1934 whose stock is currently owned by savings institutions across the United States. The agency buys residential mortgages that meet certain requirements, sells these mortgages in packages, and insures
, and the Federal Credit Union system. Many states adopted laws preventing foreclosure of homes and farms.

Relevant to current experience is the rapidity with which the economy recovered in the Depression when monetary contraction did not produce a real short-term interest rate in excess of the natural interest rate. The general lesson is the need for a monetary rule that allows the price system to function through the absence of monetary shocks, not the need for the central bank to supersede To obliterate, replace, make void, or useless.

Supersede means to take the place of, as by reason of superior worth or right. A recently enacted statute that repeals an older law is said to supersede the prior legislation.
 either the working of the price system or the allocation of credit.

REFERENCES

Balke, Nathan S., and Robert J. Gordon Robert J. Gordon is an economics professor at Northwestern University. He also holds the title of "Stanley G. Harris Professor in the social sciences".

He is an expert on measuring and explaining productivity growth, the causes of unemployment and airline economics.
. 1986. "Appendix B: Historical Data." In The American Business Cycle: Continuity and Change, edited by Robert J. Gordon. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press The University of Chicago Press is the largest university press in the United States. It is operated by the University of Chicago and publishes a wide variety of academic titles, including The Chicago Manual of Style, dozens of academic journals, including , 781-810.

Bernanke, Ben S. 2008. "Remarks on the Economic Outlook." Speech prepared for the International Monetary Conference, Barcelona, Spain, 3 June.

Blackstone, Brian. 2009. "Fed Luminaries Spar Over U.S. Inflation Target." Wall Street Journal. 20 April, A2.

Blue Chip Financial Forecasts. 2008. Various issues. New York New York, state, United States
New York, Middle Atlantic state of the United States. It is bordered by Vermont, Massachusetts, Connecticut, and the Atlantic Ocean (E), New Jersey and Pennsylvania (S), Lakes Erie and Ontario and the Canadian province of
: Aspen Publishers.

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 1943a. 1943 Annual Report. Washington, D.C.: Board of Governors.

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 1943b. Banking and Monetary Statistics: 1914-1941. Washington, D.C.: Board of Governors.

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2008. "Minutes of the Federal Open Market Committee." Washington. D.C.: Board of Governors (5 August).

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2009a. "Money Stock Measures-H.6" and "Assets and Liabilities of Commercial Banks in the U.S.-H.8." Available at www.federalreserve.gov/econresdata/releases/statisticsdata.htm.

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2009b. Table B. 100, "Balance Sheet of Households and Nonprofit Organizations." Board of Governors Flow of Funds Flow of funds

In the context of municipal bonds, refers to the statement displaying the priorities by which municipal revenue will be applied to the debt.

In the context of mutual funds, refers to the movement of money into or out of a mutual funds or between or among
 Accounts release Z. 1 (12 March). Available at www.federalreserve.gov/econresdata/releases/statisticsdata.htm.

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2009c. "The Supervisory Capital Assessment Program: Overview of Results." Washington, D.C.: Board of Governors (7 May).

Bordo, Michael D. 2008. "An Historical Perspective on the Crisis of 2007-2008." Paper presented at the Central Bank of Chile The Central Bank of Chile (Spanish: Banco Central de Chile) is the central bank of Chile. It was created by President Arturo Alessandri in 1925 and incorporated into the current Chilean Constitution by President Augusto Pinochet in 1980.  Twelfth Annual Conference on Financial Stability, Monetary Policy, and Central Banking. Santiago, Chile Santiago, officially Santiago de Chile (Spanish: ), is the capital of Chile, and the center of its largest conurbation (Greater Santiago). , 6-7 November.

Dunkelberg, William C., and Holly Wade. 2008. NFIB NFIB National Federation of Independent Business
NFIB National Foreign Intelligence Board
 Small Business Economic Trends, Monthly Report (September).

Evans, Kelly. 2008. "Price Increases Ramp Up, Sounding Inflation Alarm." Wall Street Journal, 5 August, A3.

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. "Monetary Trends." Available at http://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/mt/page6.pdf.

Financial Times. 2008. "Wages Raise Fears of Euro Zone Inflation." 14-15 June, 3.

Friedman. Milton. 1960. A Program for Monetary Stability. New York: Fordham University Press The Fordham University Press is a publishing house, a division of Fordham University, that publishes primarily in the humanities and the social sciences. Fordham University Press was established in 1907 and is headquartered in the Canisius Hall building in the Rose Hill Campus of .

Friedman, Milton. [1961] 1969. "The Lag in Effect of Monetary Policy." In The Optimum Quantity of Money and Other Essays, edited by Milton Friedman. Chicago: Aldine Publishing Company, 237-60.

Friedman, Milton. [1963] 1968. "Inflation: Causes and Consequences." In Dollars and Deficits, edited by Milton Friedman. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 21-39.

Friedman, Milton. [1964] 1969. "The Monetary Studies of the National Bureau." In The Optimum Quantity of Money and Other Essays, edited by Milton Friedman. Chicago: Aldine Publishing Company, 261-84.

Friedman, Milton. [1968] 1969. "The Role of Monetary Policy." In The Optimum Quantity of Money and Other Essays, edited by Milton Friedman. Chicago: Aldine Publishing Company, 95-110.

Friedman, Milton, and Anna J. Schwartz. 1963a. A Monetary History of the United States “American history” redirects here. For the history of the continents, see History of the Americas.
The United States of America is located in the middle of the North American continent, with Canada to the north and the United Mexican States to the south.
, 1867-1960. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Princeton University, at Princeton, N.J.; coeducational; chartered 1746, opened 1747, rechartered 1748, called the College of New Jersey until 1896. Schools and Research Facilities
 Press.

Friedman, Milton, and Anna J. Schwartz. 1963b. "Money and Business Cycles." Review of Economics and Statistics 45 (February): 32-64.

Friedman, Milton, and Anna J. Schwartz. 1970. Monetary Statistics of the United States. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Giles. Chris. 2008. "BIS Calls for World Interest Rate Rises." Financial Times. 1 July, 3.

Hetzel, Robert L. 1987. "Henry Thornton Henry Thornton is the name of:
  • Henry Thornton (abolitionist) (1760 - 1815), one of the founders of the Clapham Sect.
  • Sir Henry Thornton (railroader) (1871-1933), president of Canadian National Railway.
  • Sir Henry Gerard Thornton (1892-1977), British microbiologist
: Seminal Monetary Theorist and Father of the Modern Central Bank." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond The Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond is the headquarters of the Fifth District of the Federal Reserve located in Richmond, Virginia . It covers the District of Columbia, Maryland, Virginia, North Carolina, South Carolina and most of West Virginia.  Economic Review 73 (July/August): 3-16.

Hetzel, Robert L. 1990. "Central Banks' Independence in Historical Perspective: A Review Essay." Journal of Monetary Economics 25 (January): 165-76.

Hetzel, Robert L. 1997. "The Case for a Monetary Rule in a Constitutional Democracy." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 83 (Spring): 45-66.

Hetzel, Robert L. 2004. "How Do Central Banks Control Inflation?" Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 90 (Summer): 46-63.

Hetzel, Robert L. 2005. "What Difference Would an Inflation Target Make?" Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 91 (Spring): 45-72.

Hetzel, Robert L. 2006. "Making the Systematic Part of Monetary Policy Transparent." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 92 (Summer): 255-90.

Hetzel, Robert L. 2008a. The Monetary Policy of the Federal Reserve: A History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press Cambridge University Press (known colloquially as CUP) is a publisher given a Royal Charter by Henry VIII in 1534, and one of the two privileged presses (the other being Oxford University Press). .

Hetzel, Robert L. 2008b. "What Is the Monetary Standard, Or, How Did the Volcker-Greenspan FOMC's Tame Inflation?" Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 94 (Spring): 147-72.

Hetzel, Robert L. 2009a. "Who Should Regulate Bank Risk Taking: Regulators of the Market?" Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 95 (Spring): 161-200.

Hetzel. Robert L. 2009b. "World Recession: What Went Wrong?" In IEA IEA International Energy Agency
IEA International Environmental Agreements
IEA International Association for the Evaluation of Educational Achievement
IEA Institute of Economic Affairs
IEA Inferred from Electronic Annotation
IEA International Ergonomics Association
 Economic Affairs. Oxford: Blackwell Publishing, 17-21.

Humphrey, Thomas M. 1983. "Can the Central Bank Peg Real Interest Rates? A Survey of Classical and Neoclassical Opinion." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review 69 (September/October): 12-21.

Institute of International Finance. 2008. "Financial Crisis and Deleveraging: Challenges for 2009." Capital Markets Monitor, 18 December.

Keynes, John Maynard
:For the actor John Maynard, see John Maynard (actor).
John Maynard (unknown - March 24, 1850) was a U.S. Representative from New York.

Born in Whitestone, New York, Maynard was graduated from Union College, Schenectady, New York, 1810.
. [1930] 1971. "A Treatise on Money." In The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, Vols. 5 and 6. London: The Macmillan Press.

Kohn, Donald L. 2008. "Economic Outlook." Speech prepared for the Georgetown University Georgetown University, in the Georgetown section of Washington, D.C.; Jesuit; coeducational; founded 1789 by John Carroll, chartered 1815, inc. 1844. Its law and medical schools are noteworthy, and its archives are especially rich in letters and manuscripts by and  Wall Street Alliance, New York, 15 October.

Koopmans, Tjalling. 1947. "Measurement Without Theory." The Review of Economic Statistics 29 (August): 161-72.

Lucas, Robert E.. Jr. [1976] 1981. "Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique." In Studies in Business-Cycle Theory, edited by Robert E. Lucas, Jr. Cambridge. Mass.: The MIT MIT - Massachusetts Institute of Technology  Press.

Lucas, Robert E., Jr. [1980] 1981. "Rules, Discretion, and the Role of the Economic Advisor." In Studies in Business-Cycle Theory, edited by Robert E. Lucas, Jr. Cambridge. Mass.: The MIT Press.

Macroeconomic Advisers. 2008a. "FOMC Chatter Ahead of the June 2008 Meeting." In Monetary Policy Insights, FOMC Chatter, 18 June.

Macroeconomic Advisers. 2008b. "FOMC Chatter Ahead of the September 2008 Meeting." In Monetary Policy Insights, FOMC Chatter, 12 September.

Macroeconomic Advisers. 2008c. "The Fed's New Policy Regime." In Monetary Policy Insights. Policy Focus, 19 December.

Macroeconomic Advisers. 2009. "MPI MPI - Message Passing Interface : Charts and Tables, Product Archive, Policy Rule Spreadsheet, Backward-looking Rule." 19 March.

Mehra, Yash. 2008. "Increased Downside Risk Downside Risk

An estimation of a security's potential to suffer a decline in price if the market conditions turn bad.

Notes:
You can think of this as an estimate of the amount that you could lose on a stock or other investment.
." Memo, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, 30 July.

Meltzer, Allan H. 2003. A History of the Federal Resene, Vol. 1, 1913-1951. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Mishkin, Frederic S. 2008. "Who Do You Trust Now?" In Economic Scene, by David Leonhardt. International Herald Tribune International Herald Tribune

Daily newspaper published in Paris. It has long been the staple source of English-language news for American expatriates, tourists, and businesspeople in Europe.
, 2 October, 1.

Morley, James. 2009. "The Shape of Things to Come." In Macroeconomic Advisers Macro Focus, 27 April.

Patinkin, Don. 1948. "Price Flexibility and Full Employment." American Economic Review 38: 543-64.

Patinkin, Don. 1965. Money, Interest, and Prices. New York: Harper & Row.

Taylor, John Taylor, John, English writer
Taylor, John, 1578?–1653, English writer. He was a boatman on the Thames and hence is often called the Water Poet. A traveler throughout England and the Continent, he recorded his observations in both poetry and prose.
. 2009. Getting Off Track. Stanford, Calif.: Hoover Institution The Hoover Institution on War, Revolution and Peace is a public policy think tank and library founded by Herbert Hoover at Stanford University, his alma mater. The Institution was founded in 1919 and over time has amassed a huge archive of documentation related to President  Press.

USA Today. 2008. "Signs of a Growing Crisis." 16 July, 1.

Walter, John Walter, John

(born 1739, probably in London, Eng.—died Nov.16, 1812, Teddington, Middlesex) English newspaper publisher. Initially a coal dealer and marine-insurance underwriter, Walter acquired the patent for a printing system in 1783 and in 1785 in London began to
. 2005. "Depression-Era Bank Failures: The Great Contagion or the Great Shakeout?" Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 91 (Winter): 39-54.

Wicksell, Knut. [1898] 1962. Interest and Prices. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.

Wicksell, Knut. [1935] 1978. Lectures on Political Economy. Fairfield, N.J.: Augustus M. Kelley.

Wolf, Martin. 2008. "What the British Authorities Should Try Now." Financial Times, 31 October, 13.

The author is a senior economist and research advisor at the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. The author received helpful criticism from Michael Dotsey, Marvin Goodfriend, Marianna Kudlyak, Yash Mehra, Ann Marie Meulendyke, Motoo Haruta, John Walter
For this man's son and grandson of the same name, see John Walter (second) and John Walter (third) respectively.
For the artist John Walter see John Walter, Artist


John Walter (1738/9 - November 17, 1812), founder of
, Roy Webb, John Wood, Leland Yeager, and participants at the Rutgers History Workshop including Michael Bordo, Hugh Rockoff, John Weinberg John Livingston Weinberg (January 25, 1925 – August 7, 2006) was an American banker. He died of complications following a fall at the age of 81. He and his wife Sue Ann lived in Greenwich, Connecticut and had two children and five grandchildren. , Eugene White, and Robert Wright Robert Wright is the name of:
  • Bob Wright (baseball) (1891), early 20th century baseball pitcher
  • Robert Wright (politician) (1752–1826), early 19th century governor and congressman from Maryland
. This paper expresses the ideas of the author. Readers should not attribute them to the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. E-mail: robert.hetzel@rich.frb.org.

(1) Friedman ([1961] 1969, 255) explains the portfolio rebalancing that occurs when the central bank undertakes open-market purchases and how that rebalancing stimulates expenditure: "The [public's] new balance sheet latter an open - market purchase] is in one sense still in equilibrium ... since the open-market transaction was voluntary. ... An asset was sold for money because the terms were favorable; however ... [f]rom a longer-term view, the new balance sheet is out of equilibrium, with cash being temporarily high relative to other assets other assets

Assets of relatively small value. For financial reporting purposes, firms frequently combine small assets into a single category rather than listing each item separately.
. ... Holders of cash will seek to purchase assets. ... The key feature of this process is that it tends to raise the prices of sources of both producer and consumer services Consumer Services refers to the formulation, deformulation, technical consulting and testing of most consumer products, such as food, herbs, beverages, vitamins, pharmaceuticals, cosmetics, hair products, household cleaners, [paints, plastics, metals, waxes, coatings, minerals,  relative to the prices of the services themselves: for example, to raise the prices of houses relative to the rents of dwelling units, or the cost of purchasing a car relative to the cost of renting one. It therefore encourages the production of such sources (this is the stimulus to 'investment' ... ) and. at the same time, the direct acquisition of services rather than the source (this is the stimulus to 'consumption' ... )."

(2) Although the natural-rate hypothesis is associated with the names of Wicksell ([1898] 1962) and Friedman ([1968] 1969), it possesses a long history (Humphrey 1983). The term "natural" goes back to the Bullionist/anti-Bullionist debate of the early 19th century (Hetzel 1987). In the 1970s, the issue was whether central banks faced a menu of unemployment rates associated inversely with inflation. The combination of high inflation and high unemployment in the 1970s supported the implication of the natural-rate hypothesis that central banks cannot systematically control the level of real variables.

(3) Based on the observation that the funds rate lay below the funds rate forecast by a Taylor rule The Taylor rule is a modern monetary policy rule proposed by economist John B. Taylor that would stipulate how much the Federal Reserve should change the interest rates in response to real divergences of real GDP from potential GDP and divergences of  starting in 2002 (Taylor 2009, Figure 1) and the resulting inference that monetary policy was accommodative, Taylor (2009) argues that monetary policy under Chairman Greenspan contributed to the run-up in house prices starting in 2003 (Taylor 2009. Figure 6). Hetzel (2008a. Ch. 22, Appendix) criticizes the use of estimated Taylor rules to characterize FOMC behavior. Estimated Taylor-rule regressions are reduced forms that capture the interrelated in·ter·re·late  
tr. & intr.v. in·ter·re·lat·ed, in·ter·re·lat·ing, in·ter·re·lates
To place in or come into mutual relationship.



in
 behavior of inflation, cyclical movements in the economy, and short-term interest rates, but not structural relationships (an FOMC reaction function) running from the behavior of the economy to the FOMC's funds rate target. One important reason that estimated Taylor rules do not express a structural relationship is the misspecification that arises from omitting a central variable shaping FOMC behavior in the Volcker-Greenspan era, namely, expected inflation. Another problem with Taylor rules is that there are many different ways of measuring the right-hand variables: inflation relative to target, the output gap. and the "equilibrium" real rate that appears in the constant term. One can easily choose these variables to arrive at contradictory assessments of the stance of monetary policy. For example, Mehra (2008. Figure 22) fits the period after 2002 very well using a Taylor rule with core PCE (personal consumption expenditures) inflation.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

In 2003-4, the public was pessimistic about the future because of the decline in equity wealth after 2000, the 9/11 terrorist attack with the fear that more attacks were imminent, and the corporate governance Corporate Governance

The relationship between all the stakeholders in a company. This includes the shareholders, directors, and management of a company, as defined by the corporate charter, bylaws, formal policy, and rule of law.
 scandals such as Enron and WorldCom. At the same time, productivity growth was soaring, perhaps because of the earlier investment in information technology. The economy needed a low real rate of interest (a low cost of consuming today in terms of foregone consumption tomorrow) to provide the contemporaneous consumption and investment demand necessary to absorb the supply of goods coming onto the market, if Taylor were correct that monetary policy was expansionary starting in 2003. inflation would not have remained near the FOMC's implicit inflation target, which I take to be 2 percent core PCE inflation.

(4) This latter characterization clashes with Taylor-rule prescriptions, which require the central bank to respond directly to realized inflation. According to the characterization here of LAW with credibility, the FOMC does not respond to inflation shocks that exercise only a transitory influence on inflation as long as they leave expectations of trend inflation unchanged (see footnote 3 on the Taylor rule).

(5) The issue of whether Taylor rules usefully characterize FOMC behavior, discussed in footnote 3, should not be an issue in characterizing monetary policy in the summer of 2008. The assessment here that monetary policy became contractionary in the summer of 2008 should be consistent with Taylor-rule assessments. For the period from early 2004 through the summer of 2008, year-over-year percentage changes in the core PCE had remained steady within a narrow range of 2 percent to somewhat less than 2.5 percent. As recorded in the Minutes (Board 2008. 5) at the August 5, 2008, FOMC meeting, "most participants anticipated that core inflation would edge back down during 2009." Presumably pre·sum·a·ble  
adj.
That can be presumed or taken for granted; reasonable as a supposition: presumable causes of the disaster.
, that would place inflation at or below what I take to be the FOMC's 2 percent implicit inflation target. Although inflation remained near target, the negative output gap widened- The August 5, 2008, FOMC Minnies noted (Board 2008, 4, 6): "[T]he staff continued to expect that real GDP would rise at less than its potential rate through the first half of next year ... [M]embers em·ber  
n.
1. A small, glowing piece of coal or wood, as in a dying fire.

2. embers The smoldering coal or ash of a dying fire.
 agreed that labor markets had softened further, that financial markets remained under considerable stress, and that these factors--in conjunction with still-elevated energy prices and the ongoing housing contraction--would likely weigh on weigh on
Verb

to be oppressive or burdensome to: the expectations that weigh so heavily on diplomats' wives

Verb 1.
 economic growth in coming quarters."

However, the FOMC, focused on a concern that persistent, high headline inflation would raise the public's expectation of inflation, kept the funds rate unchanged at 2 percent. The August 5, 2008. FOMC Minnies note (Board 2008. 6): "Participants expressed significant concerns about the upside risks to inflation, especially the risk that persistent high headline inflation could result in an unmooring of long-run inflation expectations--[M]embers generally anticipated that the next policy move would likely be a tightening ..."

Taylor-rule estimation results available from Macroeconomic Advisers (2009) are striking. The "Backward-Looking Policy Rule" graph shows the funds rate forecast falling to--73 percent in 2010:03. By 2011:Q1. deflation sets in.

(6) Macroeconomic Advisers (2008b, 1). managed by former Fed governor Laurence Meyer Laurence Meyer is an economist and was a United States Federal Reserve System governor from June 1996 to January 2002.

Meyer received a B.A. (magna cum laude) from Yale University in 1965 and a Ph.D. in economics from the Massachusetts Institute of Technology in 1970.
 and whose publications discuss monetary policy through the perspective of credit markets rather than money creation, also argued that monetary policy was restrictive: "Over the period that ended in April [2008], the FOMC strategy was to ease aggressively in order to offset the tightening of financial conditions arising from wider credit spreads, more stringent lending standards, and falling equity prices. We said that the FOMC was 'running to stand still,' in that those actions did not create accommodative financial conditions but were needed to keep them from becoming significantly tighter. Since the last easing [April 2008], however, the FOMC has abandoned that strategy. Financial conditions have arguably ar·gu·a·ble  
adj.
1. Open to argument: an arguable question, still unresolved.

2. That can be argued plausibly; defensible in argument: three arguable points of law.
 lightened more severely since April than during the earlier period, and yet there has been no policy offset. This pattern has contributed importantly to the severe weakening of the economic outlook in our forecast."

(7) The Fed was not alone in encouraging the expectation of higher rates. The Financial Times (Giles 2008) in a story with the headline, "BIS Calls for World Interest Rate Rises." reported: "Malcolm Knight, outgoing general manager, and William White William White may refer to: Politics
  • William White (Secretary of State), North Carolina Secretary of State, 1798–1811
  • William White (Canadian politician), elected member of the first Council of the Northwest Territories, 1883–1885
  • William J.
, outgoing chief economist The Chief Economist is a single position job class having primary responsibility for the development, coordination, and production of economic and financial analysis. It is distinguished from the other economist positions by the broader scope of responsibility encompassing the , concluded in the report: It is not fanciful, surely, to suggest that these low levels of interest rates might inadvertently have encouraged imprudent im·pru·dent  
adj.
Unwise or indiscreet; not prudent.



im·prudent·ly adv.
 borrowing, as well as the eventual resurgence of inflation.'"

(8) Governor Kohn (2008, 1-2) characterized (he behavior of the economy during (he summer of 2008: "During (he summer, it became increasingly clear that a downshifting down·shift  
v. down·shift·ed, down·shift·ing, down·shifts

v.intr.
1. To shift a motor vehicle into a lower gear.

2. To reduce the speed, rate, or intensity of something.

3.
 in (he pace of economic activity was in train. ... [R]eal consumer outlays fell from June through August, putting real consumer spending Consumer demand or consumption is also known as personal consumption expenditure. It is the largest part of aggregate demand or effective demand at the macroeconomic level.  for the third quarter as a whole on track to decline for the first lime since 1991. Business investment also appears to have slowed over the summer. Orders and shipments for nondefense capital goods Capital Goods

Any goods used by an organization to produce other goods.

Notes:
Examples of capital goods include office buildings, equipment, and machinery.
See also: Capital Expenditure, Disinvestment



Capital goods
 have weakened, on net. in recent months, pointing to a decline in real outlays for new business equipment. Similarly, outlays for nonresidential construction projects edged lower in July and August after rising at a robust pace over the first half of this year ... [C]onditions in housing markets have remained on a downward trajectory."

(9) Macroeconomic Advisers (2008b) wrote: "By abandoning its 'offset' approach [of lowering the funds rate in response to tightening conditions in financial markets], the Federal Reserve has allowed financial conditions to tighten substantially. ... Another reason why the Fed abandoned its approach is that it has focused primarily on expanding its liquidity policies in recent months. The FOMC believes that liquidity policies are more effective tools for providing assistance to market functioning. ... But even if one accepts (as we do) that liquidity tools are better suited for helping market functioning, monetary policy still has to react to changes in the outlook."

(10) The failure of Lehman Brothers Lehman Brothers Holdings Inc. (NYSE: LEH), founded in 1850, is a diversified, global financial services firm. It is a participant in investment banking, equity and fixed income sales, research and trading, investment management, private equity, and private banking.  on September 15. 2008. created uncertainty in financial markets. Hetel (2009a) argues that the primary shock arose from a discrete increase in risk due to the sudden reversal of the prevailing assumption in financial markets that the debt of large financial institutions was insured against default by the financial safely net. A clear, consistent government policy about the extent of the financial safety net would likely have avoided the uncertainly arising from market counterparties suddenly having to learn which institutions held the debt of investment banks The following is a list of investment banks Financial conglomerates
Large financial-services conglomerates combine commercial banking and investment banking, and sometimes insurance.
 and then having to evaluate the solvency of these institutions. Nevertheless, the turmoil in financial markets and the losses incurred by banks would likely have been manageable without the emergence of worldwide recession.

(11) The initial deleveraging appeared in the decline of ABCP (asset-backed commercial paper) from $1.2 trillion in August 2007 to $800 billion in December 2007. Thereafter. ABCP outstanding basically remained steady until mid-September 2008 (declining somewhat in May 2008 and then recovering in early September). Both retail and institutional money funds grew between August 2007 and mid-September 2008. In August 2008, nonfinancial commercial paper outstanding had recovered the $200 billion level it reached in August 2007 and then grew strongly in early September 2008. Financial commercial paper remained steady over the entire period from August 2007 to mid-September 2008. The corporate Aaa rate also remained steady at 5.5 percent over this latter period. Although the KBW index of the stocks of large banks lost half its value from mid-July 2007 through mid-July 2008, it climbed 50 percent from mid-July 2008 through mid-September 2008. The steadiness of the monetary base until mid-September 2008 does not suggest any unusual demand for liquidity from the Fed (Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 2009).

(12) The quarterly annualized growth rates for final sales to domestic purchasers (GDP minus the effects of inventories and net exports) weakened in 2008:Q3 (after a modest uptick in 2008:Q2 caused by the tax rebates and fall in net exports). The figures are as follows: 2007:Q4 (- .1 percent), 2008:Q1 (.1 percent), 2008:Q2 (1.3 percent), 2008:Q3 (-2.3 percent), and 2008:Q4 (-5.7 percent). Payroll employment, which is measured in the first week of the month, declined by 284,000 in September 2008 compared to the average decline of around 60.000 from February through August (11/7/08 BLS See Bureau of Labor Statistics.  release). The decline of 240,000 jobs in October 2008 does include two weeks of the financial turmoil in the last half of September, but the lag is too short to have produced significant layoffs. The Dunkelberg and Wade (September 2008) survey of small business owners did not record deterioration in the availability of credit to small businesses between the first and last part of September 2008.

(13) On May 7, 2009, regulators released the results of "stress tests" for the 19 largest bank holding companies (BHCs), which hold 98 percent of commercial bank assets. According to the accompanying report, "At year-end 2008. capital ratios at all 19 BHCs exceeded minimum regulatory capital standards, in many cases by substantial margins." Even under the "adverse scenario" these institutions would experience "virtually no shortfall in overall Tier I capital" (Board of Governors 2009c).

(14) Statements by FOMC participants before the August 5, 2008. FOMC meeting reported by Macroeconomic Advisers (2008b) included the following:

"President Plosser (7/23/08 and 7/22/08): "Most of us agree that inflation expectations are OK. I think it's important that we act before those expectations become unhinged. ... If we remain overly accommodative in the face of these large relative price shocks to energy and other commodities, we will ensure that they will translate into more broad-based inflation that--once ingrained in expectations--will become very difficult to undo.'

President Hoenig (7/9/08): 'I think it is important to understand that we are in an accommodative position, and the implications of that [are that] the inflation we have will most likely continue in the future ...'

President Yellen (7/7/08): 'Inflation has become an increasing concern. ... On balance, I still see inflation expectations as reasonably well anchored--But the risks to inflation are likely not symmetric and they have definitely increased. We cannot and will not allow a wage-price spiral to develop."

(15) Hetzel (2008a, Ch. 20) argues that the FOMC abandoned price stability for an objective of low inflation in 2003. With the emergence in the summer of 2004 of an inflation shock due to a sustained rise in energy prices, the desired low inflation rate of about 2 percent became a base for markedly higher headline inflation. In the summer of 2008. the persistence of high headline inflation caused credibility concerns among all the world's major central banks. From this perspective, the FOMC would have been better off to have preserved the price stability that had emerged in 2003. However, price stability gives the FOMC less room to create a negative real funds rate. Board of Governors Vice Chairman Don Kohn and Paul Volcker debated the issues recently at a conference in Nashville. Tenn. (Blackstone 2009): "Mr. Voleker ... questioned how the Fed can talk about both 2% inflation and price stability. 'I don't get it.' Mr. Voleker said. ... By setting 2% as an inflation objective, the Fed is 'telling people in a generation they're going to be losing half their purchasing power.' Mr. Kohn ... replied that aiming at 2% inflation gives the Fed 'a little more room ... to react to an adverse shock to the economy' because it is easier to get its key short-term interest rate below the inflation rate, the usual remedy for recession. 'Your problem is [2%] becomes three becomes four.' Mr. Kohn told Mr. Volcker. But other central banks with a roughly 2% target haven't had that problem, he said."

(16) To understand how excessive pessimism could yield a negative natural rate, consider a hypothetical agrarian economy without money that produces wheat. Rats eat some fraction of stored wheat, say, 3 percent. If individuals are pessimistic enough about future harvests, they will be willing to store wheat despite a real interest rate of -3 percent. (Milton Friedman used this example in a 1967 course taught at the University of Chicago.)

(17) An excess supply of money would lead the public to buy Treasury securities from banks thereby reducing demand deposits and money. As a consequence of maintaining its funds rate target, the Fed would then sell Treasury securities from its portfolio to absorb the accompanying reduction in the demand for reserves by banks.

(18) At the same time, the political system needs to avoid destabilizing changes in policy that affect significant sectors of the economy. That means leaving the optimal stock of housing to the operation of market forces rather than attempting to expand it through a panoply pan·o·ply  
n. pl. pan·o·plies
1. A splendid or striking array: a panoply of colorful flags. See Synonyms at display.

2.
 of special programs and subsidies. It also means a credible commitment to a limited financial safety net that ends too-big-to-fail (Hetzel 2009a).

(19) The Lucas critique The Lucas Critique, named for Robert Lucas's work on macroeconomic policymaking, says that it's naive to try to predict the effect of a policy experiment based purely on correlations in historical data, especially high-level aggregated historical data.  argues for characterizing monetary policy as a consistent procedure (reaction function or rule) for responding to incoming information rather than as a concatenation of individual funds rate changes each of which is chosen as optimal in light of contemporary economic conditions. The central bank should behave in a consistent fashion so that the public can predict its response to shocks and. conversely, so that the central bank can influence the public's behavior in a predictable fashion (Lucas [1976] 1981). Lucas ([1980] 1981. 255) wrote: "[O]ur ability as economists to predict the responses of agents rests, in situations where expectations about the future matter, on our understanding of the stochastic By guesswork; by chance; using or containing random values.

stochastic - probabilistic
 [policy] environment agents believe themselves to be operating in. In practice, this limits the class of policies the consequences of which we can hope to assess in advance to policies generated by fixed, well understood, relatively permanent rules (or functions relating policy actions taken to the state of the economy). ... [A]nalysis of policy which utilizes economics in a scientific way necessarily involves choice among alternative stable, predictable policy rules, infrequently changed and then only after extensive professional and general discussion, minimizing (though, of course, never entirely eliminating) the role of discretionary economic management."

(20) These numbers are from Historical Statistics of the United States, Earliest Times to the Present. Millennial Edition, vol. 3. Part C, "Economic Structure and Performance" Table Cj238-250, "National banks--number, earnings, and expenses: 1869-1998." Cambridge University Press, 2006.
COPYRIGHT 2009 Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2009 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.

 Reader Opinion

Title:

Comment:



 

Article Details
Printer friendly Cite/link Email Feedback
Author:Hetzel, Robert L.
Publication:Economic Quarterly
Date:Mar 22, 2009
Words:15364
Previous Article:Should increased regulation of bank risk-taking come from regulators or from the market?
Next Article:Introduction to the New Keynesian Phillips curve.
Topics:


Related Articles
OECD foresees economy shrinking in 2009, recession setting in.
Severe recession likely to endure - IMF.
Deepening recession: UniCredit Group analysts revised their economic forecast for Bulgaria, predicting a deeper and longer recession.
Of Exit Policy, Recession and Unseen Challenges.
Can the term spread predict output growth and recessions? A survey of the literature.
Weaker still.
The nature of the current crisis and how to deal with it.
Global financial crisis and the role of China.

Terms of use | Copyright © 2014 Farlex, Inc. | Feedback | For webmasters